PD10 - Research Paper. Rozen-Bakher, Z. The Chess Game of Forming International Trade Agreements: Shaping Global Economic and Political Power

Rozen-Bakher, Z. The Chess Game of Forming International Trade Agreements: Shaping Global Economic and Political Power. Research Paper, PD10. https://www.rozen-bakher.com/research-papers/pd10

COPYRIGHT ©2021-2024 ZIVA ROZEN-BAKHER ALL RIGHTS RESERVED

Rozen-Bakher, Z.

The Chess Game of Forming International Trade Agreements: Shaping Global Economic and Political Power

Abstract

This study explores how forming a global map of bilateral, regional and multilateral trade agreements impact the shaping of the economic and political power of a country at the global level. More specifically, the study explores how each type of international trade agreement allows preserving the current position or securing a new position of superpower or ’Bloc Superpower’ or ‘Trade coalition’. The study suggests that forming bilateral trade agreements are crucial to preserve or secure a new position of superpower/’Bloc Superpower’ because it allows creating a global map of bilateral trade agreements with allies or targeted allies, regardless of the geographical proximity. However, regional trade agreements give the opportunity to create a ’Bloc Superpower’ between regional countries that each of them has not enough economy and political power to become a superpower. Nevertheless, the most promising type of international trade agreement is the multilateral trade agreement outside WTO because it allows forming a ‘Trade Coalition’ among a group of allies from different geographical areas, which may result in geopolitics change. The study emphasizes that winning the Chess Game of international trade agreements can be accomplished through getting good conditions of ‘Origin Product’ and ‘Rules of Origin’, still, balancing is needed between ‘Mercantilism style’ and ‘Strategic Ally’ to be a superpower or ’Bloc Superpower’.

Keywords: Economic Power, Political Power, International Trade Agreements, International Trade, Trade Wars

Introduction

The topic of international trade agreements considers the most important issue to advance international trade and FDI (Büthe & Milner, 2008; Dür et al., 2014; MacDermott, 2007).  From the viewpoint of MNEs, free trade agreements (FTAs) provide competitive advantages to an MNE from a home country that has greater lucrative FTAs over an MNE from a home country that has fewer lucrative FTAs.  However, the international relations of a home country with other countries, as well as its geopolitics position (Gupta et al., 2018) alongside its power position at the global level, impact crucially the scope and gainful of international trade agreements that a home country has (e.g. Kelly, 2012; Pastor, 1994; Wang, 2004; Wang, 2005). More importantly, the friendly relations, or vice versa, hostile relations of a home country with other countries, shape the scope and worth of FTAs that a home country has. In other words, the allies of a home country, as well as its enemies/rivals and even the allies of its enemies/rivals determine the scope and worth of FTAs that a home country has.  Hence, the characteristics of foreign relations of a home country with other countries determine the ability of a home country to form greater lucrative international trade agreements compared to other countries, such as the characteristics of foreign relations in terms of allies (Haim, 2016; Gowa, 1994), rivals (Hong, 2007; Corning, 2011), enemies (Liberman, 1996; Nabi & Nasim, 2001), open conflicts (Martin et al., 2012), wars (Barbieri & Levy, 1999), diplomatic relations or lack of diplomatic relations (Abdullah, 2018), boycotts (Stone & Trew, 2019; Weiss, 2007), sanctions (Nasre Esfahani & Rasoulinezhad, 2017), embargo (White, 2019), geopolitics position (Gupta et al., 2018), global power position (Ahumada, 2018; Kirshner, 2007), trade wars (Bouët & Laborde, 2018; Buongiorno & Johnston, 2018; Larres, 2020; Noland, 2017), regional position (Galal & Lawrence, 2001; Lee & Shin, 2006; Lawrence, 2006), membership in defence treaties (e.g. NATO) or in military alliances (Powers, 2004), membership in international organizations (e.g. WTO) (Sachs & Woo, 2003) and more.

In spite of the above, the global order and geopolitics in a specific period of time also impact the scope of international trade agreements of a home country, regardless of the characteristics of its foreign relations. That particularly applies to regional and multinational trade agreements. In other words, there is a difference between a global order characterised by the hegemony of a single superpower and a global order characterised by two, three or more superpowers (Demko, 2018) or even by a ‘Bloc Superpower’.  ‘Bloc Superpower’ refers to a group of allies that have shared power on the rationale of economies of scale (Krugman, 1980; Stigler, 1958), such as the EU bloc that its regional economies of scale have driven the shaping of its position as a ‘Bloc Superpower’. Consequently, the political power of the EU bloc has changed the geopolitics order (Maull, 2005). Nonetheless, ‘Bloc Superpower’ includes countries that none of them is superpowers, such as the EU bloc that its members cannot be considered as a superpower like the USA, even the powerful countries among the EU countries, such as Germany and France. Still, the EU bloc includes enough powerful countries that together they have the ability to become a ‘Bloc Superpower’, and for that reason to change the global order. Notwithstanding, a group of allies from different geographical areas worldwide can establish a ‘Trade Coalition’ based on common interests. Still, the main difference between ‘Bloc Superpower’ and ‘Trade Coalition’ is that ‘Trade Coalition’ may include or not superpowers, while ‘Bloc Superpower’ does not include superpowers, yet the bloc includes enough powerful countries that together create ‘Bloc Superpower’. Given that, the global order since the cold war was transformed from two superpowers namely, the USA and the Union of Soviet Socialist Republics (USSR) to a single superpower-USA until the previous decade (Demko, 2018). However, in the last decade, it has transformed into a new global order that includes at least three superpowers namely, the USA, Russia and China (Hurrell, 2006; Jacques, 2009; Smith, 2012) alongside the EU bloc as a ‘Bloc Superpower’. Therefore, any certain global order impacts the formation of bilateral, regional and multilateral trade agreements at the global level, apart from the international relations of a certain home country with other countries that affect the forming of FTAs.

Considering the above, this study explores how international trade agreements impact the shaping of the political power of a country at the global level.  In other words, the study investigates the forming of FTAs from the viewpoint of obtaining political power. To address it, the study explores the principles of a free trade agreement (FTA) with a focus on the differences between the three main types of FTAs namely, bilateral, regional and multilateral trade agreements to understand how forming a global map of FTAs impact the shaping position of superpower or ’Bloc Superpower’ or ‘Trade coalition’.

The paper is organized, as follow. The next section discusses the principles of FTA to understand the rules of the game of FTAs, while the following section discusses the differences between the three main types of FTAs - bilateral, regional and multilateral - from the geopolitics perspective. The final section presents the conclusions and discusses the implications for policymakers. 

The Rules of Chess Game ─ Principles of FTA: Checkmate via ‘Rules of Origin’

FTA is an international trade agreement between two or more countries. Under an FTA, import tariffs, export duties, quotas and other restrictions and barriers are lifted by the countries, either partially or fully, immediately or gradually, nonetheless, each country maintains an independent trade policy towards other countries that are not parties to the agreement (Gantz, 2003; Krueger, 1997; Lawrence, 2006; O'Sullivan et al., 2008; Plummer et al., 2011; Schott, 2004; Song & Yuan, 2012; Weerakoon, 2001).

Forming any FTA is based on several important principles, yet any FTA is different from other ones because each FTA has a different combination of how the principles of FTA are implemented.  In other words, the combination of how the principles are implemented in the FTA determines the unique characteristics of each FTA. Given that, any political declaration by leaders about achieving FTA with other countries has no significant meaning but how exactly the FTA creates competitive advantages to the country. In other words, it may be wrong to assume that any FTA leads to a Win-Win for all sides. Some FTAs indeed lead to Win-Win, while other FTAs lead to Win-Lose namely, one side has significant benefits from the trade agreement, while other sides have fewer competitive advantages, and in some FTAs, it even may lead to competitive disadvantages that may backfire the national economy. Therefore, how the principles of FTA are implemented from the viewpoint of each side determines if the FTA is Win-Win or Win-Lose.  

Considering the outlined above, FTA is based on several principles, which their combination and implementation determine the specific conditions of each FTA, as follow (Büthe & Milner, 2008; Kepaptsoglou et al., 2009; Gantz, 2003; Krueger, 2012; Mukunoki, 2017; O'Sullivan et al., 2008; Plummer et al., 2011; Song & Yuan, 2012; WTO, 2019):

·      Removal of Direct and Indirect Restrictions. FTA is supposed to lead to the lifting of direct restrictions and barriers, such as import tariffs and export quotas. FTA is also supposed to lead to the removal of indirect restrictions and barriers related to international trade and FDI, such as technical standards, government subsidies, industry regulation, and indirect taxation.

·      Exemptions. Many FTAs include partially or fully exemptions from tariffs and duties on goods between the countries who signed the agreement. That particularly applies in cases of FTAs between developed countries and developing countries or between powerful countries and their allies (Jacobs et al., 2018). Nevertheless, when a country imposes high tariffs, still, it may give exemptions from high tariffs for some products that are required to the local market, such as the exemptions that Trump administration gave to hundreds of types of Chinese products (Cheng, 2019).

·      Non-restrictions on Forming Other FTAs. FTA is based on the important principle that each country has the right to keep an independent trade policy. That's reflected on the right to sign additional FTAs with other countries that are based either on the same or different tariffs and duties. Hence, a country can sign on different FTAs with multiple countries simultaneously, regardless of if those countries have or not FTAs between of them. Nevertheless, this principle does not apply to EU countries because the EU bloc acts as a single country in relation to international trade.  Moreover, a specific FTA of a home country can give an advantage to a certain host country over another one due to superior terms of one FTA compared to inferior terms of another FTA. For example, Israel has several FTAs, such as with the USA, Canada and Jordan, but each of these FTAs has different terms of trade compared to other FTAs (Aminoff, 1991; Azmeh, 2015; Hofley & Gudofsky, 1997; Israeli Ministry of Economy, 2018; Nugent & Abdel-Latif, 2010; Saif, 2006; Tovias & Al-Khouri, 2004). In other words, any trade agreement may have different tariff rates for all products or certain products, as well as for all sectors or certain sectors.

·      ‘Origin Product’ and ‘Rules of Origin’. One of the fundamental principles of FTA is the specific 'rules of origin' of a certain product, which can be different in each trade agreement.  In general, a product is considered as an 'origin product' in FTA when the product is fully produced in the country includes raw materials used in its production. In other words, an imported product, or a product that its production is based on import raw materials cannot be considered as an 'origin product' in FTAs. For example, the different status of North Ireland from other parts of the UK in Boris Johnson's new Brexit deal has become a problematic issue for North Ireland because of the principle of 'rules of origin' that is led to a situation that the 'origin product' of North Ireland is not the same 'origin product' in the rest parts of the UK (Sampson, 2019).

·      ‘Partially Origin Product', Some FTAs also include ‘partially origin product', depends on the specific 'rules of origin' of a product in each FTA. ‘Partially origin product' refers to a product that is fully produced in the country that signed the FTA, but with the ability to use raw materials that imported from a third country. Given that, the same product can be considered as an 'origin product' in one FTA, while in another FTA, it won't be considered as an 'origin product'. For example, the Qualified Industrial Zones (QIZ) trade agreement between Israel and Jordan allows Israel to manufacture products in Jordan and then to export these products to the USA as part of the trade agreement between Israel and the USA, despite that the production does not carry out in Israel but in Jordan (Aminoff, 1991; Azmeh, 2015; Israeli Ministry of Economy, 2018; Nugent & Abdel-Latif, 2010; Saif, 2006; Tovias & Al-Khouri, 2004).

·      ‘Cumulative Rules of Origin Product’. ‘Cumulative rules of origin product’ refers to a product that is considered as an 'origin product', despite that the production is based on raw materials from other countries that have FTAs with the home country.  In other words, in ‘Partially origin product', some of the raw materials can be imported from other countries, regardless if the home country has FTAs with these countries. However, in ‘Cumulative rules of origin product’, the raw materials can be imported from other countries that have FTAs with the home country. Thus, the main difference between them if exist or not FTAs with the countries that the raw materials imported from. Importantly, each FTA has different 'cumulative rules of origin'. Given that, in one FTA, a home country may be able to use raw materials from a specific third country, while in another FTA, the same home country will not be able to use the raw materials from the same third country.

·      Direct Shipping. Direct shipping refers to the principle that an 'origin product' should be sent directly between the countries that signed the FTA. In other words, a home country cannot send products directly from a third country to the destination country unless if the 'cumulative rules of origin' allow sending the product from a third country who has also FTA with the home country. Direct shipping tries to prevent manipulation in the implementation of FTAs because of the concern that a home country will produce a product in a low-cost third country, but still will declare on the product as an 'origin product'.

Simultaneous Exhibition of Multiple Checkmate: Shaping Position of Superpower or ’Bloc Superpower’ or ‘Trade Coalition’ via Forming Global Map of Lucrative Bilateral, Regional, and Multilateral Trade Agreements 

According to the principles of FTA, any country tries to create a map of lucrative bilateral, regional, and multilateral trade agreements to increase the economic power of the country, resulting in shaping the political power position of the country at the global level. However, forming a map of lucrative trade agreements at a country level is not an easy task, and it may be challenging as a Chess Game because of the complexity of the three layers of FTAs namely, bilateral, regional, and multilateral trade agreements. In other words, each type of FTAs - bilateral, regional, and multilateral - has a different way to increase the power of the country at the global level, economically and politically. Considering that, this section discusses the differences between bilateral, regional, and multilateral trade agreements from the viewpoint of obtaining economic and political power. 

Bilateral Trade Agreements

Bilateral trade agreements take place between two countries with friendly relationships and common interests in various fields, such as based on political, economic, technological, and cultural grounds (Abeyratne, 2013; Capling, 2008; Frankel et al., 1997; Moroz & Back, 1981; Sen, 2010; Strodthoff, 2014; Tovias & Al-Khouri, 2004; Urata, 2015; Verico, 2017; WTO-RTA, 2018).

From the viewpoint of MNEs, bilateral trade agreements impact dramatically the competitive advantages of MNEs from home markets that have many bilateral trade agreements over MNEs from home countries that have fewer bilateral trade agreements. In other words, an MNE that its home country has greater bilateral trade agreements, then MNE can gain greater competitive advantages over MNEs from other home countries that have fewer bilateral trade agreements.  Hence, the scope of an MNE activity is not determined only by the ability of the management of an MNE to leverage the firm activities in global markets but it's significantly affected also by the scope of the bilateral trade agreements that its home country has compared to other home countries. Therefore, the activity of an MNE is not determined only by the ability of its management to increase the market size of the firm in host countries but it's also significantly affected by the international relations of the MNE’s home country with other host countries, which is reflected through the scope of the bilateral trade agreements that a home country has compared to other home countries. To illustrate it, Australia and Japan have a bilateral trade agreement (Australia Government, 2019; Capling, 2008; Japan Export.Gov, 2018), but Australia and Israel do not have a bilateral trade agreement. Thereby, this gives to Japanese MNEs competitive advantages in Australia over Israeli MNEs who operate in Australia because Australia and Israel do not have a bilateral trade agreement. In other words, the import tariffs for Israeli MNEs in Australia are higher than those for Japanese MNEs in Australia because Australia and Japan have a bilateral trade agreement. Considering that, the competitive advantages of bilateral trade agreements of a certain home country are determined based on the gap in the import tariffs between the home country and other home countries. Consequently, the price of a product of an MNE in a host country is influenced dramatically by the import tariffs of the MNE's home country in the host country. Hence, the lowest tariff a home country has in a trade agreement with a certain host country, a lower competitive price can be set by an MNE from this home country in the host market.  That's gap can be range from a few percentages to dozens of percentages depending on various factors such as, if exists or not an FTA between the MNE's home country and the target host country, the 'rules of origin' in the FTA, the specific product, the specific tariffs in the certain industry, and even the geographical location in the host country. Importantly, it can be argued that the gap in import tariffs between countries is the foremost ground for trade wars (Larres, 2020) because it reflects the competitive advantage of an MNE in a certain host market over its rivals.

However, it’s important to distinguish between bilateral FTA of ‘regional bloc’ with a single country versus bilateral FTA between two single countries. There are many FTAs between a single country and a ‘regional bloc’ (Rutherford et al., 1997; Siles-Brügge, 2011; Tovias & Al-Khouri, 2004), such as the FTAs between Israel and MERCOSUR (Israeli Ministry of Economy, 2018). This kind of FTA is considered as a bilateral trade agreement because a single country signs an international trade agreement with a bloc of regional countries, so under such agreement, the ‘regional bloc’ acts as a 'single country'. More importantly, countries that are members of a particular regional trade agreement like MERCOSUR have a greater economic and political power to gain better international trade agreements with other single countries compared to any single country among MERCOSUR that will try to form bilateral trade agreements with other single countries. That’s based on the rationale of economies of scale (Krugman, 1980; Stigler, 1958) namely, any group of countries has more economic and political power to form better international trade agreements over a single country among the group in terms of tariffs, 'rules of origin', 'cumulative rules of origin product’ and more. In other words, economies of scale give an advantage to a bigger economy or activity over a small one, so usually, a group of countries has more power to get better FTAs compared to a single country.  The rationale of economies of scale may also explain the criticism against Brexit because it is expected to weaken the economies of scale of the UK, especially if the Union (Union-England, Scotland, Wales and Northern Ireland) will split after the Brexit. Thereby, if after the Brexit, Scotland and Northern Ireland will split from the Union as expectedly (Macnab, 2019), formally or under a different status (Gamp, 2019; Sampson, 2019), then the economic power position of England will be reduced in related to its ability to get good terms of FTAs due to the weakening of economies of scale. In other words, today, the Union (UK) reflects economies of scale of 67 million people (World Bank, 2019) and £1.748 trillion GVA-Gross Value Added (UK-Office for National Statistics, 2018).  However, if the Union (UK) will split after the Brexit as expected, then the economies of scale of England and Wales will be 55 million people and £1.537 trillion GVA (exclude Scotland and Northern Ireland). Nevertheless, the economies of scale of the UK is supposed to be reduced significantly after the Brexit even if the Union won’t split.  The EU bloc reflects economies of scale of 513 million people and $22.0 trillion GDP (PPP) compared to the UK’s economies of scale of 67 million people and $3.1trillion GDP (PPP) (Eurostat, 2019; IMF, 2019; World Bank, 2019). Hence, in any way, Brexit is supposed to weaken the economic power position of the UK (Dhingra et al., 2018), especially regarding its ability to form lucrative FTAs compared to the pre- Brexit period due to the weakening of economies of scale of UK (Stone, 2017). Paradoxically, Brexit leaders have assumed that the Brexit will allow the UK to form greater lucrative bilateral FTAs compared to the pre-Brexit period when the UK was part of the EU bloc. However, based on the principle of economies of scale (Krugman, 1980; Stigler, 1958), it’s supposed to be the opposite. To illustrate it, let’s assume that a single country would like to form a bilateral FTA with a ‘regional bloc’ or with another single country. Thereby, who has more power to get more beneficial FTA, the ‘regional bloc’ that worth $20.0 trillion GDP or a single country that worth $2 trillion GDP?. Obviously, the ‘regional bloc’. Thus, the EU bloc has more power to get lucrative bilateral FTAs compared to the UK as a single country outside the EU bloc. 

In light of the above, the power position of a home country, economically and politically, determines the quantity of lucrative bilateral trade agreements that a home country can form compared to other home countries. Given that, only a home country that succeeds to form many lucrative bilateral trade agreements with other countries can preserve its position or secure its new position as a superpower or part of a ’Bloc Superpower’ or a 'Trade Coalition'. Moreover, under the reality of the global economy in the 21 century, defence capabilities may not be sufficient to preserve position or to secure a new position as a superpower or Bloc Superpower’ but only if the country/bloc also secures their global economy power via FTAs. In other words, globalization has changed the ‘Rules of Game’ of the global order compared to the period of the ‘cold war’. Today is needed a combination of political power via defence capabilities alongside economic power via international trade and FDI to preserve the current position or to secure a new position as a superpower or ’Bloc Superpower’. That's can be accomplished via forming a global map of lucrative bilateral FTAs with allies and targeted allies.    

Regional Trade Agreements

Regional trade agreements take place among a group of countries located in the same geographic region with an emphasis on the trade gain amid the geographical proximity between the countries (Dent, 2003; Fadeyi et al., 2014; Frankel et al., 1997; Koo et al., 1991; Valdes et al., 2015; WTO-RTA, 2018). However, regional trade agreements usually take place between regional countries that have friendly, economic, and political ties (Frankel et al., 1997; Koo et al., 1991; WTO-RTA, 2018), and even the same political ideology or economy ideology. For example, the establishment of the EU bloc began among Western European countries that share the same political ideology of democracy (Magen et al., 2009), and only after that, Eastern European countries have started to join the EU bloc after their transformation to democratic countries (Raik, 2006). Nonetheless, there are Eastern EU countries in which their democracy has started to deteriorate after their joining the EU bloc (Mueller, 2014), such as Hungary and Poland. Thereby, the deterioration of democracy in Hungary and Poland has raised concerns among EU leaders that the current democracy standards in these EU countries contradict the democratic values of the EU bloc (Baczynska, 2020). Notwithstanding, there are regional FTAs among countries that don’t share the same political ideology, such as the new trade agreement of Regional Comprehensive Economic Partnership (RCEP) between 15 countries that including countries like China that has Communist political ideology, while Australia and Japan that have Democracy political ideology (Vu & Nguyen, 2020).

In spite of the above, from the viewpoint of a country, there is a significant difference between bilateral and regional trade agreements. In bilateral trade agreements, exist friendly ties and common interests between the two countries which is the rationale for forming the bilateral trade agreement, regardless of the physical distance between the two countries, such as the bilateral trade agreement between Chile and Australia (Strodthoff, 2014). Hence, in a bilateral trade agreement, the focus is on the friendly ties and common interests between the two countries, rather than on the physical distance, such as the trade agreement between the USA and Israel (Aminoff, 1991; Israeli Ministry of Economy, 2018). In contrast, in regional trade agreements, the geographical closeness provides an economic advantage for the creation of regional trade agreements, such as the MERCOSUR trade agreement in South America that currently includes four full-member countries: Argentina, Brazil, Paraguay and Uruguay (MERCOSUR, 2018). Importantly, regional trade agreements are formed even if the countries in the same geographical area have less friendly ties or have diversity in the economic ideology, such as the diversity in the economic ideology that exists among the EU bloc, such as the Netherlands that has liberal open economy (Sluyterman, 2010), while Portugal that has socialist economy (Hatton, 2019).

However, from the geopolitics perspective, regional trade agreements less impact the ability to preserve position or secure a new position as a superpower compared to bilateral and multilateral FTAs. That's because regional FTAs give the same competitive advantages for all countries that belong to a certain regional FTA. Nevertheless, regional FTAs give the opportunity for the creation of ‘Bloc Superpower’, such as the EU bloc that shapes its position as a ‘Bloc Superpower’ at the global level. Consequently, the political and economic power of the EU bloc has led to a change in the global order, which is reflected in the global decision-making namely, any significant decision at the global level won’t pass without the approval of the EU bloc.    

Multilateral Trade Agreements

Multilateral FTAs refer to international trade agreements among a group of countries with common interests from different geographical areas. The foremost multilateral FTAs is the GATT that was signed after the end of WWII by 23 countries to promote free trade at the global level through reducing or eliminating tariffs without imposing direct or indirect new tariffs (Bhagwati, 2017; Brewer & Young, 2000; Coppolaro, 2018a, 2018b; Dam, 1970; Hamblet, 2011; Srinivasan, 2019; Verwey, 1990; WTO, 2019; Zeiler, 2012). However, over the years, the number of countries of GATT/WTO has increased significantly namely, 62 countries in 1967 (Kennedy Round), 102 countries in 1979 (Tokyo Round), 123 countries in 1994 (Uruguay Round) and 141 countries in 2001 (Start of Doha Round), while today it's includes more than 160 member countries (Coppolaro, 2018b; Evans, 1971; Hamblet, 2011; Kumar, 2018; McRae & Thomas, 1983; Moak, 2017; Preeg, 2012; Ritzer, 2012; Winham, 2014; WTO, 2019). That's mean that WTO includes today most of the countries worldwide. Therefore, multilateral trade agreements under WTO do not impact the political power position of any member country because it's not give any significant advantage for one member country over other ones compared to multilateral trade agreements outside WTO. In other words, the non-discrimination policy of WTO (Hamblet, 2011) has no meaning because each member country has the right to form bilateral, regional and multilateral trade agreements outside WTO (McKenzie, 2010).  This argument may explain the trend of creation of many bilateral, regional and multilateral trade agreements outside WTO (Levy, 1997) over the last two decades because under a large number of member countries (WTO, 2019) GATT doesn’t provide any competitive advantages to any member country of WTO nor protection against discrimination. Nevertheless, WTO could still provide a platform for stabilising global trade to prevent trade wars (Larres, 2020), still, multilateral FTAs under WTO has no impact on shaping the political power position of a country.

However, multilateral FTAs outside WTO can shape the position of superpower or ’Bloc Superpower’ or ‘Trade Coalition’, such as the multilateral trade agreement BRICS that includes a group of five big emerging countries with friendly ties and common interests from three different continents namely, Brazil, Russia, India, China, and South Africa (BRICS, 2018; Jadhav, 2012; Wilson & Purushothaman, 2003). It can be argued that BRICS includes two superpowers namely, Russia and China, so BRICS allow both Russia and China to increase their superpower position, or at least to create a ‘Bloc Superpower’ of five big countries. Notably, BRICS includes around half of the world's population (3.2 Billion people) with a worth quarter of the world GDP (21 Trillion GDP) (World Bank, 2019), so it cannot be ignored in terms of global power.

Moreover, forming multilateral FTAs outside WTO between countries from different geographical areas worldwide allow establishing also ‘Trade Coalition’ based on common objectives or common ideology. However, there is a difference between a ‘Trade Coalition’ and ‘Bloc Superpower’. ‘Bloc Superpower’ does not include superpowers, still, the bloc includes enough powerful countries that together they can influence the global order as a ‘Bloc Superpower’. However, the ‘Trade Coalition’ may include one superpower or even more, which strengthens the position of each superpower while giving benefits to their allies. Alternatively, the ‘Trade Coalition’ can be formed without superpowers based on the rationale that the economies of scale are supposed to increase the power of each member in the coalition. Hence, friendly ties, common political interests, common objectives and similar ideology may motivate countries from different geographical areas to create multilateral FTAs to strengthen their political position via ‘Trade Coalition’.  

Conclusions and Policy Implications

This study explores how forming a global map of bilateral, regional and multilateral FTAs impact the shaping of the economic and political power of a country at the global level. More specifically, the study explores the differences between bilateral, regional and multilateral trade agreements in terms of how each type of FTAs allows preserving the current position or securing a new position of superpower or ’Bloc Superpower’ or ‘Trade coalition’. That’s based on the rationale that the scope of lucrative bilateral, regional and multilateral FTAs that a home country has, impact significantly the shaping of its geopolitics position (Pastor, 1994; Wang, 2004) and power position at the global level (Wang, 2005).  

The study suggests that forming bilateral FTAs are crucial to preserve or secure a new position of superpower/’Bloc Superpower’ because it allows creating a global map of bilateral FTAs with allies or targeted allies, regardless of the geographical proximity. Nevertheless, under this power objective, the superpower/’Bloc Superpower’ may give lucrative FTAs to its allies to preserve its position or to secure its new position as superpower/’Bloc Superpower’, or vice versa, the superpower/’Bloc Superpower’ may force bilateral FTAs on its allies or targeted allies in a ‘Mercantilism style’ (Conti, 2018; LaHaye, 2017; Mun, 1895), such as the objective of ‘America First’ of Trump (Janusch & Mucha, 2017). Nonetheless, under this power objective, the superpower/’Bloc Superpower’ may form bilateral FTAs under three scenarios (S-Superpower/A-ally): Firstly, Win-S/Win-A scenario in case of equal relations between the superpower and its powerful ally. Secondly, Win-S/Lose-A scenario in case of ‘Mercantilism style’ (Conti, 2018; LaHaye, 2017; Mun, 1895). In this case, the superpower/’Bloc Superpower’ may take advantage economically of its allies in return for providing defence assurance (e.g. in case of wars or conflicts) or political backing (e.g. veto on unfavourite voting in United Nations against the ally). Thirdly, Lose-S/Win-A scenario in case of ‘Strategic Ally’. This case particularly applies when at least two superpower/’Bloc Superpower’ compete to preserve or secure special relations with an important ally/targeted new ally. Notably, in the case of ‘Strategic Ally’, the superpower/’Bloc Superpower’ may also provide defence assurance and political backing to its ally as in the case of ‘Mercantilism style’, but without taking economic advantage of its strategical ally. In other words, in the case of ‘Mercantilism style’, the cost of the defence assurance and political backing is on the ally, while in the case of ‘Strategic Ally, the cost of the defence assurance and political backing is on the superpower/’Bloc Superpower’, only for the privilege to be superpower/’Bloc Superpower’. In spite of the above, any country should avoid forming bilateral FTAs based on a Lose-Lose scenario.

The study also indicates that regional FTAs give the opportunity to create ’Bloc Superpower’ between regional countries that each of them has not enough economy and political power to become a superpower by itself, such as the powerful countries Germany and France that none of them has currently the necessary power to become a superpower like USA, Russia and China. Still, under the EU bloc, Germany and France have the ability to lead the EU bloc as a ‘Bloc Superpower’.  

However, the study concluded that the most promising type of FTA in terms of obtaining economic and political power is the multilateral FTA outside WTO because it allows forming a ‘Trade Coalition’ among a group of allies from different geographical areas, which has the potential to change the global order. Nevertheless, forming a ‘Trade Coalition’ can lead to three different scenarios. In the first scenario, the ‘Trade Coalition’ may include at least one superpower/’Bloc Superpower’, which allow increasing the economic and political power of the superpower/’Bloc Superpower’. In the second scenario, the ‘Trade Coalition’ may include several powerful countries without superpowers/’Bloc Superpower’, yet this ‘Trade Coalition’ has the potential to transform into a ‘Bloc Superpower’. In the third scenario, the ‘Trade Coalition’ may include several ‘unimportant’ countries namely, none of them has the political power to form lucrative FTAs by itself but together based on the rationale of economies of scale (Krugman, 1980; Stigler, 1958), they have the ability to form lucrative FTAs.

Finally, when countries establish FTAs, policymakers should look in-depth at the conditions of FTAs in terms of how the ‘Origin Product’, ‘Rules of Origin’, ‘Partially origin product' and ‘Cumulative Rules of Origin Product’ define in the FTA. Policymakers should aware that winning Checkmate in FTAs can be only accomplished through getting good conditions of ‘Origin Product’ and ‘Rules of Origin’.

References

Abdullah, R. (2018). China-Malaysia Relations and Foreign Policy. Routledge.

Abeyratne, S. (2013). Integration of Sri Lanka into Indian supply chains under the bilateral free trade agreement. South Asia Economic Journal, 14(2), 275-292.

Ahumada, J. M. (2018). Chile’s trade policies in the context of US contemporary imperialism: The free trade agenda and the loss of national autonomy. In The Continuing Imperialism of Free Trade (pp. 125-136). Routledge.

Aminoff, N. A. (1991). United States-Israel Free Trade Area Agreement of 1985: In Theory and Practice, The. J. World Trade, 25, 5.

Australia Government. (2019). Australia's free trade agreements (FTAs). Retrieved 31.10.2019. https://dfat.gov.au/trade/agreements/Pages/trade-agreements.aspx

Azmeh, S. (2015). Transient global value chains and preferential trade agreements: rules of origin in US trade agreements with Jordan and Egypt. Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy and Society, 8(3), 475-490.

Baczynska, G. (2020 September 30). EU slams Poland, Hungary as cash-for-democracy fight heats up. Reuters. https://uk.reuters.com/article/uk-eu-democracy/eu-criticises-poland-hungary-in-first-democracy-report-idUKKBN26L1FH

Barbieri, K., & Levy, J. S. (1999). Sleeping with the enemy: The impact of war on trade. Journal of peace research, 36(4), 463-479.

Bergsten, C. F. (2005). Rescuing the Doha Round. Foreign Affairs, 84(7).

Bhagwati, J. (2017). Trade liberalization among LDCs, trade theory, and GATT rules. In Value, Capital and Growth (pp. 21-44). Routledge.

Bouët, A., & Laborde, D. (2018). US trade wars in the twenty‐first century with emerging countries: Make America and its partners lose again. The World Economy, 41(9), 2276-2319.

Brewer, T.L. & Young, S. ((2000. The Multilateral Investment System and Multinational Enterprises. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

BRICS. (2018). BRICS. http://brics.itamaraty.gov.br/

Buongiorno, J., & Johnston, C. (2018). Potential Effects of US Protectionism and Trade Wars on the Global Forest Sector. Forest Science, 64(2), 121-128.

Büthe, T. & Milner, H. V. (2008). The Politics of Foreign Direct Investment into Developing Countries: Increasing FDI through International Trade Agreements?. American Journal of Political Science, 52: 741–762.

Capling, A. (2008). Preferential trade agreements as instruments of foreign policy: an Australia–Japan free trade agreement and its implications for the Asia Pacific region. The Pacific Review, 21(1), 27-43.

Cheng, E. (2019, September 20). Trump grants tariff exemptions to plastic straws, dog leashes and more from China. CNBC. https://www.cnbc.com/2019/09/20/china-us-trade-war-400-chinese-products-to-be-exempted-from-tariffs.html

Conti, T. V. (2018). Mercantilism: a materialist approach. Scandinavian Economic History Review, 66(2), 186-200.

Coppolaro, L. (2018a). General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT). The Encyclopedia of Diplomacy, 1-13.

Coppolaro, L. (2018b). In the Shadow of Globalization: The European Community and the United States in the GATT Negotiations of the Tokyo Round (1973–1979). The International History Review, 40(4), 752-773.

Corning, G. P. (2011). Trade regionalism in a realist East Asia: rival visions and competitive bilateralism. Asian Perspective, 35(2), 259-286.

Dam, K. W. (1970). The GATT:Law and international economic organization. Chicago, London.

Demko, G. J. (2018). Reordering the world: Geopolitical perspectives on the 21st century. Routledge.

Dent, C. (2003). Networking the region? The emergence and impact of Asia-Pacific bilateral free trade agreement projects. The Pacific Review, 16(1), 1-28.

Dhingra, S., Ottaviano, G., Rappoport, V., Sampson, T., & Thomas, C. (2018). UK trade and FDI: A post‐Brexit perspective. Papers in Regional Science97(1), 9-24.

Dür, A., Baccini, L., & Elsig, M. (2014). The design of international trade agreements: Introducing a new dataset. The Review of International Organizations, 9(3), 353-375.

Eurostat. (2019). Population on 1 January 2019. European Commission. https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/web/products-datasets/-/TPS00001

Evans, J. W. (1971). The Kennedy Round in American trade policy. The twilight of the GATT?. Kumar, M. (2018). The Mother of All Rounds. In Negotiation Dynamics of the WTO (pp. 1-65). Palgrave Macmillan, Singapore.

Fadeyi, O. A., Bahta, T. Y., Ogundeji, A. A., & Willemse, B. J. (2014). Impacts of the SADC free trade agreement on South African agricultural trade. Outlook on AGRICULTURE, 43(1), 53-59.

Frankel, J. A., Stein, E., & Wei, S. J. (1997). Regional trading blocs in the world economic system. Peterson Institute.

Galal, A., & Lawrence, R. Z. (Eds.). (2001). Building Bridges: An Egypt-US Free Trade Agreement. Brookings Institution Press.

Gamp, J. (2019, October 5). Scottish independence: Thousands march in Edinburgh - 'Radical and instant independence!'. EXPRESS. https://www.express.co.uk/news/uk/1186923/scottish-independence-latest-edinburgh-news-indyref2-nicola-sturgeon-royal-mile

Gantz, D. A. (2003). The evolution of FTA investment provisions: from NAFTA to the United States-Chile Free Trade Agreement. Am. U. Int'l L. Rev., 19, 679.

Gantz, D. A. (2018). The Trump Approach to Trade Negotiations: Risks in Presenting a Renegotiated NAFTA to a Skeptical Congress. Issue Brief, 9.

Gowa, J. (1994). Allies, adversaries, and international trade. Princeton University Press.

Gupta, R., Gozgor, G., Kaya, H., & Demir, E. (2018). Effects of geopolitical risks on trade flows: Evidence from the gravity model. Eurasian Economic Review, 1-16.

Haim, D. A. (2016). Alliance networks and trade: The effect of indirect political alliances on bilateral trade flows. Journal of Peace Research, 53(3), 472-490.

Hamblet, W. C. (2011). General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT). In Encyclopedia of Global Justice (pp. 381-382). Springer, Dordrecht.

Hatton, B. (2019 October 7). Portugal’s Socialists prepare 4 more years in government. AP. https://apnews.com/article/acf7bda41f52421b9e52a84610cac00d

Hofley, R. J., & Gudofsky, J. L. (1997). The Canada-Israel Free Trade Agreement–Levelling the Playing Field. Journal of World Trade, 31(2), 153-174.

Hong, Z. (2007). India and China: rivals or partners in Southeast Asia?. Contemporary Southeast Asia, 121-142.

Hurrell, A. (2006). Hegemony, liberalism and global order: what space for would-be great powers?. International affairs, 82(1), 1-19.

IMF. (2019). World Economic Outlook Database. International Monetary Fund. https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2019/01/weodata/index.aspx

Israeli Ministry of Economy. (2018). Trade Agreements and Bilateral issues of Israel. Israeli Ministry of Economy. http://economy.gov.il/English/InternationalAffairs/ForeignTradeAdministration/TradePolicyAgreements/BilateralAgreements/Pages/BilateralAgreements.aspx

Jacobs, J., Mayeda, A., & Olorunnipa, T. (2018). Canada, Mexico to Get Initial Exemption From Trump Tariffs, Official Says. BLOOMBERG, 8 March 2018. https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2018-03-08/canada-mexico-to-get-initial-exemption-from-steel-tariffs

Jacques, M. (2009). When China rules the world: The end of the western world and the birth of a new global order. Penguin.

Jadhav, P. (2012). Determinants of foreign direct investment in BRICS economies: Analysis of economic, institutional and political factor. Procedia-Social and Behavioral Sciences, 37, 5-14.

Janusch, H., & Mucha, W. (2017). America First: Power and Geopolitics in US Trade Policy under President Trump. S&F Sicherheit und Frieden, 35(3), 8-12.

Jones, K. (2012). Things Fall Apart: Doha and the End of the Post-War Trade Consensus. World Economics, 13(4), 125-152.

Kelly, R. E. (2012). Korea–European Union relations: beyond the FTA?. International Relations of the Asia-Pacific, 12(1), 101-132.

Kepaptsoglou, K., Tsamboulas, D., Karlaftis, M. G., & Marzano, V. (2009). Free trade agreement effects in the Mediterranean region: an analytic approach based on sure gravity model. Transportation Research Record, 2097(1), 88-96.

Kirshner, O. (2007). Superpower politics: The triumph of free trade in postwar America. Critical Review, 19(4), 523-542.

Koo, W. W., Uhm, I. H., & Golz, J. T. (1991). Bilateral Trade Relationship Between the United States and Canada: Implications of the Free Trade Agreement. Contemporary Economic Policy, 9(4), 56-69.

Krueger, A. O. (1997). Free trade agreements versus customs unions. Journal of Development Economics, 54(1), 169-187.

Krueger, A. O. (2012). Free trade agreements as protectionist devices: Rules of origin. In Trade, Theory and Econometrics (pp. 113-124). Routledge.

Krugman, P. (1980). Scale economies, product differentiation, and the pattern of trade. The American Economic Review70(5), 950-959.

LaHaye, L. (2017). Mercantilism. The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 1-4.

Larres, K. (2020). Trump’s trade wars: America, China, Europe, and global disorder. Journal of Transatlantic Studies18(1), 103-129.

Lawrence, R. Z. (2006). US-Middle East Trade Agreement: A Circle of Opportunity?, A. Peterson Institute Press: All Books.

Lee, J. W., & Shin, K. (2006). Does regionalism lead to more global trade integration in East Asia?. The North American Journal of Economics and Finance, 17(3), 283-301.

Levy, P. I. (1997). A political-economic analysis of free-trade agreements. The American Economic Review, 506-519.

Liberman, P. (1996). Trading with the enemy: security and relative economic gains. International Security, 21(1), 147-175.

MacDermott, R. (2007). Regional trade agreement and foreign direct investment. The North American Journal of Economics and Finance, 18(1), 107-116

Macnab, S. (2019, October 24). Poll: Majority say Brexit will lead to 'break up of the union'. SCOTSMAN. https://www.scotsman.com/news/politics/poll-majority-say-brexit-will-lead-to-break-up-of-the-union-1-5032411

Magen, A., Risse, T., & McFaul, M. (Eds.). (2009). Promoting democracy and the rule of law: American and European strategies. Springer.

Martin, P., Mayer, T., & Thoenig, M. (2012). The geography of conflicts and regional trade agreements. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 4(4), 1-35.

Maull, H. W. (2005). Europe and the new balance of global order. International Affairs, 81(4), 775-799.

McKenzie, F. (2010). The GATT–EEC Collision: The Challenge of Regional Trade Blocs to the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade, 1950–67. The International History Review, 32(2), 229-252.

McRae, D. M., & Thomas, J. C. (1983). The GATT and Multilateral Treaty Making: The Tokyo Round. American Journal of International Law, 77(1), 51-83.

MERCOSUR. (2018). The Southern Common Market. MERCOSUR. https://www.mercosur.int/en/

Moak, K. (2017). GATT, Rounds of Negotiations, and the World Trade Organization. In Developed Nations and the Economic Impact of Globalization (pp. 97-120). Palgrave Macmillan, Cham.

Moroz, A. R., & Back, K. J. (1981). Prospects for a Canada-United States bilateral free trade agreement: the other side of the fence. International Journal, 36(4), 827-850.

Mueller, J. W. (2014). Eastern Europe Goes South: Disappearing Democracy in the EU's Newest Members. Foreign Affairs93(2), 14-19.

Mukunoki, H. (2017). The welfare effect of a free trade agreement in the presence of foreign direct investment and rules of origin. Review of International Economics, 25(4), 733-759.

Mun, T. (1895 (Reprint of the 1664 edition)). England's treasure by forraign trade. New York, MacMillan.

Nabi, I., & Nasim, A. (2001). Trading with the enemy: a case for liberalizing Pakistan–India trade. In Regionalism and globalization (pp. 190-218). Routledge.

Nasre Esfahani, M., & Rasoulinezhad, E. (2017). Iran’s trade policy of Asianization and de-Europeanization under sanctions. Journal of Economic Studies, 44(4), 552-567.

Noland, M. (2017). The Risks and Costs of Trade Wars. US-China Cooperation in a Changing Global Economy.

Nugent, J., & Abdel-Latif, A. (2010, April). A quiz on the net benefits of trade creation and trade diversion in the QIZs of Jordan and Egypt. In Economic Research Forum Working Papers (Vol. 514).

O'Sullivan, A., Sheffrin, S. M., & Perez, S. J. (2008). Economics: Principles, applications, and tools. Pearson Education.

Pastor, R. A. (1994). The North American Free Trade Agreement: Hemispheric and Geopolitical Implications. The International Executive, 36(1), 3-31.

Pearson, D. (2015). What Makes for an Effective Free Trade Agreement? Examination of Theory and Evidence. In A New Paradigm for International Business (pp. 1-34). Springer, Singapore.

Plummer, M. G., Cheong, D., & Hamanaka, S. (2011). Methodology for impact assessment of free trade agreements. Asian Development Bank.

Powers, K. (2004). Regional trade agreements as military alliances. International Interactions, 30(4), 373-395.

Preeg, E. (2012). The Uruguay Round Negotiations and the Creation of the WTO. The Oxford Handbook on The World Trade Organization, 122.

Raik, K. (2006). Promoting democracy through civil society: How to step up the EU's policy towards the Eastern Neighbourhood (No. 237). CEPS.

Ritzer, G. (2012). General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade. The Wiley‐Blackwell Encyclopedia of Globalization.

Rutherford, T. F., Rutström, E. E., & Tarr, D. (1997). Morocco's free trade agreement with the EU: A quantitative assessment. Economic modelling, 14(2), 237-269.

Sachs, J. D., & Woo, W. T. (2003). China's economic growth after WTO membership. Journal of Chinese Economic and Business Studies, 1(1), 1-31.

Saif, I. (2006). The Socio-Economic Implications of the Qualified Industrial Zones in Jordan. Amman, Jordan: Center for Strategic Studies, University of Jordan.

Sampson, T. (2019, October 26). Boris Johnson’s Brexit deal poses a rules-of-origin conundrum. FINANCIAL TIMES. https://www.ft.com/content/280a05ce-f6fe-11e9-bbe1-4db3476c5ff0

Schott, J. J. (Ed.). (2004). Free trade agreements: US strategies and priorities. Columbia University Press.

Sen, R. (2010). New regionalism in Asia: the case of Singapore-Australia bilateral free trade agreement. International Journal of Business and Globalisation, 4(4), 359-398.

Siles-Brügge, G. (2011). Resisting protectionism after the crisis: Strategic economic discourse and the EU–Korea free trade agreement. New Political Economy, 16(5), 627-653.

Smith, M. A. (2012). Power in the changing global order: the US, Russia and China. Polity.

Song, G., & Yuan, W. J. (2012). China's free trade agreement strategies. The Washington Quarterly, 35(4), 107-119.

Stigler, G. J. (1958). The economies of scale. The Journal of Law and Economics, 1, 54-71.

Srinivasan, T. N. (2019). Developing countries and the multilateral trading system: From GATT to the Uruguay Round and the future. Routledge.

Stone, J. (2017). Brexit: Free trade deals will have limited benefits for UK, warns Philip Hammond. INDEPENDENT, 7 July 2017. https://www.independent.co.uk/news/uk/politics/brexit-trade-deals-uk-benefits-limited-philip-hammond-eu-warning-a7829951.html

Stone, J., & Trew, B. (2019, November 12). Products from illegal Israeli settlements must be labelled, EU’s highest court rules. INDEPENDENT. https://www.independent.co.uk/news/world/europe/israel-illegal-settlement-products-label-eu-high-court-palestine-a9199651.html

Strodthoff, I. (2014). Shortening Imagined Distance: Toward the Bilateral Free Trade Agreement. In Chile and Australia (pp. 73-96). Palgrave Macmillan, New York.

Tovias, A., & Al-Khouri, R. (2004). An Empirical Estimation of the Potential Economic Effects of a Bilateral Free Trade Area Agreement between Israel and Jordan in the Context of the Euro-Mediterranean Partnership1. Israel Affairs, 10(3), 138-158.

UK-Office for National Statistics. (2018). Regional gross value added (balanced), UK:

1998 to 2016. UK-Office for National Statistics.

Urata, S. (2015). Postwar Japanese Trade Policy: A Shift from Multilateral GATT/WTO to Bilateral/Regional FTA Regimes. In The Political Economy of Japanese Trade Policy (pp. 41-70). Palgrave Macmillan, London.

Valdes, R., Von Cramon-Taubadel, S., & Engler, A. (2015). Transaction costs and trade liberalization: An empirical perspective from the MERCOSUR agreement. Food Policy, 55, 109-116.

Verico, K. (2017). The Impact of Bilateral FTA: Bilateral Level Analysis. In The Future of the ASEAN Economic Integration (pp. 113-144). Palgrave Macmillan, London.

Verwey, W. D. (1990). The Principles of a New International Economic Order and the Law of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT). Leiden Journal of International Law, 3(2), 117-142.

Vu, K. & Nguyen, P. (2020, November 15). Asia forms world's biggest trade bloc, a China-backed group excluding U.S. Reuters. https://www.reuters.com/article/asean-trade-summit-rcep-signing-idUSKBN27V03K

Wang, J. (2004). China's Regional Trade Agreements: The Law, Geopolitics, and Impact on the Multilateral Trading System. SYBIL, 8, 119.

Wang, V. W. C. (2005). The Logic of China–ASEAN FTA. China and Southeast Asia: Global Changes and Regional Challenges, 17-41.

Weerakoon, D. (2001). Indo-Sri Lanka Free Trade Agreement: How Free is It?. Economic and Political Weekly, 627-629.

Weiss, M. A. (2007, April). Arab League Boycott of Israel. LIBRARY OF CONGRESS WASHINGTON DC CONGRESSIONAL RESEARCH SERVICE.

White, N. D. (2019). Ending the US embargo of Cuba: international law in dispute. Journal of Latin American Studies, 51(1), 163-186.

Wilson, D., & Purushothaman, R. (2003). Dreaming with BRICs: The path to 2050. Global economics paper, (99), 1.

Winham, G. R. (2014). International trade and the Tokyo Round negotiation (Vol. 463). Princeton University Press.

World Bank (2019). World Development Indicators (WDI). Washington D.C: World Bank.

WTO. (2019). World Trade Organization. WTO. https://www.wto.org/index.htm

WTO-RTA. (2018). Regional trade agreements (RTA). WTO-RTA World Trade Organization. Last updated on October 29, 2018. http://rtais.wto.org/UI/PublicAllRTAList.aspx

Zeiler, T. W. (2012). THE EXPANDING MANDATE OF THE GATT! THE FIRST SEVEN ROUNDS. The Oxford Handbook on The World Trade Organization, 102.

Dr. Ziva Rozen-Bakher

Dr. Ziva Rozen-Bakher

Researcher in Risks for Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) and International Trade

Political Risks, Economic Risks, Strategic Risks

https://www.rozen-bakher.com/
Previous
Previous

PD9 - Research Paper. Rozen-Bakher, Z. Restrictions on International Trade and Foreign Direct Investment (FDI): Nationalism-Mercantilism versus Trade Liberalism

Next
Next

PD11 - Research Paper. Rozen-Bakher, Z. Is the World Trade Organization (WTO) has a Future under the Mechanism of Consensus in Decision-Making?: A New Framework for Achieving Successful Rounds