PD5 - Research Paper. Rozen-Bakher, Z. A Regime Type as a Location Factor of FDI: Democracy, Communism, Absolute Monarchy, Religious Regime, and Military Regime

Rozen-Bakher, Z. A Regime Type as a Location Factor of FDI: Democracy, Communism, Absolute Monarchy, Religious Regime, and Military Regime. Research Paper, PD5. https://www.rozen-bakher.com/research-papers/pd5

COPYRIGHT ©2021-2024 ZIVA ROZEN-BAKHER ALL RIGHTS RESERVED

Rozen-Bakher, Z.

A Regime Type as a Location Factor of FDI: Democracy, Communism, Absolute Monarchy, Religious Regime, and Military Regime

Abstract

This study explored the regime type as a location factor of FDI to predict the political risk for FDI Inward in a host country due to a dynamic of regime transformation. The study examined five regime types: democratic regime, communist regime, absolute monarchy regime, religious regime, and military regime. The study revealed that exists a low risk for FDI Inward in a full democratic regime, yet it can be transformed into a partially democratic regime via legal tactics, which may increase the political risk. The likelihood for a regime transformation in the remaining communist regimes is relatively low, particularly via a democratic revolution, despite the lack of political rights in communism. In religious regimes, if the share of minorities’ religious and seculars is too big to ignore, then it may lead to resistance to religious coercion that may end in a regime transformation, which may increase the political risk for FDI. In an absolute monarchy, FDI Inward has the potential for high profits, but it may involve high political risk, particularly in a kingdom with a history of a ‘monarchy coup’. A military regime can provide the highest profits, yet it may involve a ‘bribe risk’ and a ‘coup risk’. The study concluded that a low risk of FDI is associated with low profitability of FDI mainly in a full democratic regime, while a high risk of FDI is associated with the high profitability of FDI mainly in military regimes and absolute monarchy regimes.

Keywords: Democracy, Communism, Absolute Monarchy, Religious Regime, Military Regime, Foreign Direct Investment (FDI), Location Factor, Regime Transformation, Political Risk.

Introduction

The Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) literature considers the political instability as one of the crucial location factors that determine FDI Inward (Aguiar et al., 2012; Bano et al., 2009; Burger et al., 2016; Busse & Hefeker, 2007; Cooke,2001; Habib & Zurawicki, 2002; Gastanaga et al., 1998; Globerman & Shapiro, 2003; Godinez & Liu, 2018; Loree & Guisinger, 1995; Nigh, 1985; Rafat & Farahani, 2019; Rashid et al., 2017; Rozen-Bakher, 2017; Samimi et al., 2011; Sethi et al., 2003; Trevino & Mixon, 2004), which is founded theoretically on the OLI framework of Eclectic Paradigm (Dunning & Lundan, 2008). Political instability can occur due to undermining of the political conditions at the country level because of various reasons: Firstly, political instability can occur due to internal conflicts, such as ethnic tensions (De Nevers, 1993; De Vries, 2002; Rafat & Farahani, 2019), religious tensions (Rafat & Farahani, 2019; Wijsen, 2004), protests (Brancati, 2016; Cai, 2010; Della Porta, 2020; Mooijman et al., 2018; Nossiter, 2019; Psimitis, 2011), strikes (Cooke, 2001; Wise, 2019), guerrilla wars (Krcmaric, 2018; landau, 1993), terrorism by internal actors (Enders & Sandler, 1996; Subramaniam, 2012), resistance movements (Jean-Klein, 2001; Wagnr, 2008), civil wars (O’balance, 1998), riots (Nossiter, 2019; Wilkinson, 2009), and coups (Elumami & Laessing, 2019; Gasiorowski, 1987; Thyne & Powell, 2016). Secondly, political instability can also occur due to external conflicts (Rafat & Farahani, 2019) such as, wars (Barbieri & Levy, 1999; Brecher & Geist, 1980; Chaudhry, 1991), terrorism by external actors (Khan & Estrada, 2016), embargo (Andreas, 2005; White, 2019), international boycotts (Stone & Trew, 2019; Weiss, 2007), international sanctions (Nasre Esfahani & Rasoulinezhad, 2017), diplomatic crises (Faizullaev & Cornut, 2017), and trade wars (Bouët & Laborde, 2018; Noland, 2017). Thirdly, a fall of governments (Golder & Thomas, 2014) and repeated general elections can also undermine the political stability in a country (Busse & Hefeker, 2007), such as the four repeated general elections in Israel over 2 years (04/2019, 09/2019, 03/2020, 03/2021) (The Knesset, 2021). Even dispute over election results can also lead to deterioration of political stability, such as the civilian-military riot that was occurred in the USA following the call of Trump to protest the results of the presidential election in 2020 (Segers, 2021), or as the case of the military coup in Myanmar following the strife over the election results (Stoakes & Safi, 2021). Fourthly, political instability occurs when governments make unexpected changes in government policy (Trevino & Mixon, 2004) or even when governments plan to make a drastic policy change. For example, Brexit led to an internal fight among the UK political actors that was reflected in unusual political maneuverers, such as taking control of the 'Commons Business' by MPs to prevent no-deal (Wills, 2019), or forcing the resignation of PM Theresa May (Stewart, 2019) by the Tories Party in order to replace her by the Hard-Brexiter, PM Boris Johnson (Roberts, 2019), or even the unlawful shutdown of the UK parliament by  PM Boris Johnson (Brown, 2019; Shirbon & Holden, 2019). Fifthly, even a failure of a government to implement its obligations and agreements can undermine political stability (Globerman & Shapiro, 2003; Li & Resnick, 2003; Trevino & Mixon, 2004). Sixthly, lack of personal security, problems with property rights, restrictions on press freedom, and corruption may also undermine the political stability in a country (Busse & Hefeker, 2007; Habib & Zurawicki, 2002; Gastanaga et al., 1998; Globerman & Shapiro, 2003; Godinez & Liu, 2018; Li & Resnick, 2003; Trevino & Mixon, 2004).

Considering the outlined above, previous FDI studies showed that political instability as a location factor negatively impacts the scope of FDI Inward (Dunning & Lundan, 2008), especially in developing countries (Rozen-Bakher, 2017). Nigh (1985) found that internal political conflicts (e.g. demonstrations) in a host country negatively affected FDI inward, but only in developing countries, while external political conflicts (e.g. wars) negatively affected FDI inward in both developing and developed countries. However, Loree & Guisinger (1995) showed that in 1977, political stability had no significant influence on FDI inward among 48 host countries, while in 1982, the trend changed, and it showed a significant impact that may be explained by the changing in attitude toward political risk (Loree & Guisinger, 1995). Gastanaga et al. (1998) found that a low level of corruption significantly and positively affected FDI inward in 49 developing host countries during the years 1970-1995. Cooke (2001) found that multiple working strikes significantly and negatively affected the volume of FDI inward in developing host countries. Globerman & Shapiro (2003) found that corruption, violation of human rights and freedom significantly and negatively affected FDI inward in 143 host countries during the years 1995-1997. Trevino & Mixon (2004) showed that political instability significantly and negatively affected the volume of FDI inward in 7 developing host countries in Latin America during the years 1988-1995. Busse & Hefeker (2007) showed that governmental stability and lack of internal conflicts, external conflicts, corruption, and ethnic tensions significantly and positively affected FDI inward in 83 developing host countries during the years 1984-2003. Bano et al. (2009) showed that political instability had a long-term adverse effect on FDI inflows to Pakistan in the pre-global financial crisis. Samimi et al., (2011) showed that political stability had a detrimental effect on FDI inward in 16 Islamic countries (OIC) during the years 2002-2009. Burger et al., (2016) showed that political shocks negatively influenced greenfield FDI Inward to the Middle East and North Africa in the non-resource tradable sectors during the years 2003-2012, while natural resource sectors and non-tradable activities apparently showed insensitive to such political shocks. Rozen-Bakher (2017) found that economic and political stability significantly and positively affected FDI inward, yet only in developing countries during the years 2000-2008. Rashid et al., (2017) showed that political stability positively influenced FDI inflows in the long run in 15 Asia Pacific countries during the years 2000-2013. Rafat & Farahani (2019) showed that external conflict, ethnic tensions, and religious tensions were highly significant factors in the determination of FDI inflows in Iran during the years 1985-2016.

In the spite of the above, there is a difference between a location factor of political instability and a location factor of regime type. Political instability reflects the level of unstable political conditions in a country as outlined above. Conversely, a regime type reflects the characterises of a regime in terms of how leadership manages the country institutions and the level of freedom, regardless of the current political conditions, stable or unstable. Hence, each regime type has a different leadership type that manging the freedom in a different way namely, full-democracy or partly-democracy or full-authoritarian, which affects FDI inward differently in terms of scope and risk. Considering that, political instability as a location factor allows knowing about the deterioration of political stability in a country that was already occurred in the PAST, while the regime type as a location factor allows predicting the political risk in the FUTURE. From the viewpoint of policymakers and Multinational Enterprises (MNEs), there is a fundamental difference between knowing about unstable political conditions that were already occurred in the PAST in a host country versus predicting political risks that may occur in the future in a host country. To illustrate it, on 01 February 2021, the world waked up to the news about the military coup in Myanmar (Mahtani & Lynn, 2021). Thereby, this coup will appear in future political instability reports about Myanmar. Still, these reports will not be helpful for those countries or MNEs that already conducted FDI Inward in Myanmar before the coup because any military coup leads to significant negative implications to the business community, especially to foreign firms as in the case of Myanmar (Keyes, 2021). To fill the research gap outlined above, this study explores the regime type as a location factor of FDI to predict the risk for FDI in a host country, rather than focusing on the causes for political instability that occurred in the past. To address it, the study explores the regime type at two layers of analysis namely, the characteristics of regime type and the level of freedom with the aim of predicting how the regime type impacts the risk for FDI Inward. Hence, the study compares regime types based on characteristics of regime type namely, Democracy versus Communism versus Absolute Monarchy versus Religious Regime versus Military Regime. The study also compares regime types based on the level of freedom namely, full democracy versus partial democracy versus repressive regime.

The paper is organized, as follows. The next section includes three parts. The first part discusses the characteristics of regime type by comparing Democracy versus Communism versus Absolute Monarchy versus Religious Regime versus Military Regime. The second part discusses the level of freedom among regimes by comparing a full democratic regime versus a partial democratic regime versus a repressive regime. The third part discusses how regime type as a location factor impacts the risk for FDI Inward. The final section discusses the conclusion.

Regime Type – Characteristics and Level of Freedom: Two Layers of Political Risk for FDI Inward

The literature mainly classifies the regime type based on the characteristics of each regime type, such as democracy versus communism. However, regime type should be sorted based on two layers to get a deeper understanding of the political risk of each regime. Hence, the study classifies the regime type based on two layers of political risk namely, layer I based on the characteristics of each regime type and layer II based on the level of freedom amongst regimes. That assumes that the level of freedom may not be similar among regimes from the same regime type based on the same characteristics. For example, exists various of the level of freedom among democratic regimes, as well as among repressive regimes. In other words, looking only at one layer will not provide the full deeper understanding that requires for analysing the political risk of regime type with the aim of predicting the risk for conducting FDI Inward in a certain regime. Hence, this study explores the two layers of regime types in terms of characteristics and level of freedom to reveal the potential future risk for FDI at the level of a host country, as discussed below.        

Layer I – Characteristics of Regime Types: Democratic Regime vs. Communist Regime vs. Absolute Monarchy Regime vs. Religious Regime vs. Military Regime

The first layer of regime type is based on the characteristics of each regime type. Thereby, if we sort the regimes worldwide that exist in the 21st century based on characteristics, then it shows that exist five main regime types namely, Democracy, Communism, Absolute Monarchy, Religious Regime and Military Regime, as follows.     

Democratic Regime. In a democratic regime (Achen & Bartels, 2016; Dahl, 2020; O’donell, 1994; Schmitter & Karl, 1991), the government gets the power to manage the country through a free general election, while legislature and courts serve as ‘checks and balances’ to preserve the democracy and freedom. However, there are two main types of democratic regime namely, Liberal Democracy and Social Democracy that differ from each other at the economic and political levels, such as The Netherlands as liberal democracy (Andeweg & Irwin, 2002) versus Portugal as social democracy (Hatton, 2019). At the economic level, liberal democracy (Carson, 2017; Dunleavy, 1987; Held & McGrew, 1993; Gillies et al., 2002) is based on the idea of capitalism namely, a free-market economy without government intervention in the market through regulation. Thereby, in an open economy, monopolies and cartels are eliminated, governmental companies are privatized (Hodge, 2018; Levi-Faur & Rozen-Bachar, 2011), and property rights are protected (Mukand & Rodrik, 2020). Consequently, in a liberal democracy, fewer restrictions and barriers exist regarding FDI. Conversely, social democracy (Berman & Snegovaya, 2019; Brus & Laski, 1991; Carson, 2017; Esping-Andersen, 2017; Huber et al., 1993; Przeworski, 1986) is based on the idea that government should act for the common good. Thus, social democracy places great emphasis on the welfare-state (Barr, 2020), so the government uses regulatory measures to control the availability and prices of public services and basic goods. Therefore, in a mixed economy, exist monopolies or limited competition in regulated sectors, while free competition in other sectors, so certain industries are restricted to FDI inward. At the political level, liberal democracy more preserves individual rights (Mill, 1859), while social democracy more preserves the collective rights, such as the differences between liberal democracy and social democracy regarding the rights for euthanasia (Kouwenhoven et al., 2019) or abortion (Machado & Maciel, 2017) or LGBT (Ayoub & Paternotte, 2019).  Hence, in a liberal democracy, the risk for transformation from a democratic regime to a repressive regime is low due to the stronghold of freedom values, while in social democracy, the risk for transformation from a democratic regime to a repressive regime is higher, particularly if the regime was previously a communist regime or military regime or absolute monarchy, especially in the near past, such as the cases of Eastern European countries (Baczynska, 2020; Mueller, 2014).

Communist Regime. In a communist regime, (Brodsgaard & Yongnian, 2006; Engels & Marx, 2004; Hardt, 2010; Kornai, 1992), the communist party runs the country without elements of democracy, such as general election and freedom. At the economic level, the production, assets, and services in a country are owned and managed by the country (Engels & Marx, 2004). Thereby, a communist regime acts in a style of command economy namely, the government involves in the production of local products in terms of types of products, quantity, and prices.  Thus, in communism, exists a high level of government ownership with monopolies in many sectors, yet a communist regime opens to FDI Inward, but under significant restrictions that align to a communist regime (Gorg, 2005; Kornai, 1992). Besides, communism is based on the idea that the wealth of the country should distribute equally among citizens (Engels & Marx, 2004), such as in the former communist regime, the Union of Soviet Socialist Republics (USSR) (Lane, 2019; Rigby, 2019). Today, exist only four communist regimes worldwide namely, China, Cuba, Laos, and Vietnam (Brodsgaard & Yongnian, 2006; CIA, 2021; Horowitz, 1995). Even though, some refer to North Korea as a communist regime (Saxonberg, 2013; Scobell, 2005), despite that its ideology does not base on communism but on Juche ideology (Suh, 2012), yet the Juche regime in North Korea is similar to characteristics of a communist regime. Importantly, despite that a communist regime restricts political and freedom rights, then paradoxically, the remaining communist regimes worldwide have relatively long-term political stability (Wright & Bak, 2016; Zheng, 2017). Thus, the likelihood of regime transformation in these communist regimes is relatively low, particularly via revolution, especially in China (Saxonberg, 2013). China has relatively political stability (Zheng, 2017), while the unrest in Hong Kong may not represent the mainland of China because Hong Kong transformed overnight from a full-democracy to a repressive regime when the sovereignty of the UK in Hong Kong ended in 1997 (Ash et al., 2000). Thus, obviously that such dramatic transformation will lead to political unrest (Cheung, 2009; Newburn, 2020). Nevertheless, many explanations were given for the political stability in China, such as ‘too big to fall’, sophisticated internal public policy that keeps the ‘flames low’, relatively open economy, advanced technology, developed infrastructure, splitting the political communist ideology from the economy and more (Burns & Zhiren, 2010; Jiang & Esarey, 2018; Yue & Yang, 2017; Zheng, 2017). Even the policy of ‘Hidden Unemployment’ (Porket, 1995) to keep the unemployment low by creating over quantity of jobs that are not really required to fulfil the demand of production and service (Wong & Kinglun, 1997), may also explain the political stability in China. In other words, it’s not obvious in the 21st century that a capitalist-democracy will succeed to create jobs for a population of 1400 million people without unemployment, poverty and even homelessness, such as India (Bhardwaj, 2018; Dat et al., 2020; Thiyagarajan et al., 2018) that its population size is similar to China (Around 1,400 million people (IMF, 2021), still, in democratic India, the GDP per capita is 6,283 US$ versus 17,206 US$ in the communist China (IMF, 2021). Thus, ‘jobs protection’ via ‘hidden unemployment’ that exists in communism compared to ‘actual unemployment’ in capitalism may additionally explain the relative political stability in China, despite the lack of political rights. Importantly, the openness of China to capitalist countries (e.g. news, tourism, study, work, and trade) may paradoxically reduce the resistance to communism in China because of poverty, unemployment and homelessness that exist in capitalist countries (Dat et al., 2020; Thiyagarajan et al., 2018) and visible via global news. Given that, a bigger country size may reduce the likelihood of regime transformation in big communist countries. Nevertheless, perhaps, the best explanation for the relative political stability in China is the survival of China as a big communist country compared to the big communist country USSR (Population of 288 million (WPR, 2021)) that collapsed in 1991 (Dallin, 1992). USSR was suffered from an ineffective economy and corruption (Dallin, 1992; Heinzen, 2007), while China puts efforts to create an effective economy (Burns & Zhiren, 2010) that open to trade and investment (Riedel et al., 2020) alongside anti-corruption policy (He, 2000). Given that, the expectation that the relative political stability that exists today in communist regimes may continue in the future, despite the lack of political and freedom rights, especially in big communist countries.

Absolute Monarchy Regime. In an absolute monarchy regime (Alaoudh, 2017; Blum. 2017; Swann & Felix, 2013), the monarch rises to power not based on a general election or elite election but based on the right to be the heir to the throne, unrelatedly if the heir fits or not, to be a ruler in terms of age, skills, and personal characteristics. Hence, in an absolute monarchy, a king, an heir to the throne, and the royal family have unlimited power in running the country, such as the absolute monarchy in Saudi Arabia (Alaoudh, 2017). However, it is important to distinguish between an absolute monarchy and a constitutional monarchy. In a constitutional monarchy (Barker, 1944; Shore, 2018), the monarch has a symbolic power under the constitution of the country, while the government and parliament are in charge to manage the country, yet the expectation that the monarch will not interfere with the managing of political affairs, such as the constitutional monarchy in England (Barker, 1944) and Spain (Gilmour, 1985). Today, most of the existing monarchies are constitutional monarchies, rather than absolute monarchies (Blum, 2017). Even though there are countries that are formally considered a constitutional monarchy, yet the sovereign uses his power to influence the political arena (Shore, 2018). For example, in 2014-2016, several amendments were made to Jordan constitution that gives to King Jordan the sole authority to appoint important key positions (e.g. Chief of Constitutional court, Head of Military, and Intelligence Director) (Al-Sharif, 2014; Younis, 2016), despite it contradicts the principle of separation of power that should be in a constitutional monarchy. Even the monarch of Liechtenstein got in 2012 unlimited power via a controversial referendum that allows him to veto any law and even to dismiss governments and ministers (Langley, 2013), which contradicts the principles of constitutional monarchy. Hence, in the 21st century, there are countries that are formally considered a constitutional monarchy, but they de-facto reflect a combination of constitutional monarchy/absolute monarchy, such as Jordan (Al-Sharif, 2014) and Liechtenstein (Langley, 2013).

Religious Regime. Religion reflects a set of beliefs in the mighty power of one god (monotheism) or several gods (monolatry) that are responsible for the universe (Wach, 2016; Woodhead et al., 2016). Thus, a person who believes in a certain religion is required to follow the rules of the religion and to engage in religious worship. Hence, in a religious regime (Beeman, 1986; Driessen, 2014; Hamayotsu, 2020), the government runs the country based on the laws of the dominant religion, while other religious minorities or even secular persons must obey the rules of the dominant religion. Therefore, in a religious regime, exist religious coercion (Cohn, 2002; Pinkkus & Meyer, 2008) against the religious minorities by imposing religious restrictions according to the ruling religion to preserve its dominant (Ahdar, 2012; Cohen & Susser, 2000; Friedmann, 2003), either among minorities from other religious or from the same religion, such as the tension between the Jewish Orthodox religious and the Jewish Liberal religious (Cohen-Almagor, 2017; Helfand, 2019). Therefore, in religious regimes, conflicts more often arise due to the constant tension between individual freedom and the religious rules that are imposed by the dominant religion in the country (Cohen & Susser, 2000; Cohn, 2002). Nonetheless, there is a difference among religious regimes regards the level of religious coercion. In other words, the level of religious coercion defines the level of religious freedom in a certain religious regime (Pinkkus & Meyer, 2008). Even though, inherently, a religious regime cannot be considered as a full democracy (Smooha, 2002) because of the religious coercion that jeopardizes the freedom even if exist elements of democracy, such as the case of Israel (Cohen & Susser, 2000; Cohn, 2002; Smooha, 2002) that de-facto runs the country as a Jewish religious regime. Notably, there are many countries that the dominant religion is important, such as the Catholic-Christianity in Italy, still, despite the most important Christianity figure, the Pope sits in Vatican-Italy, there is no religious coercion of Christianity against other religious minorities in Italy (Ferrari, 2018). However, in a religious regime, the religious coercion of the dominant religion impacts any aspects of the daily life of other religious minorities without giving them real religious freedom (Pinkkus & Meyer, 2008). For example, in Iran, any woman must put a hijab even if the woman is not Muslim or secular (Koo & Han, 2018). Even in Israel exists significant religious coercion against other religious minorities (e.g. Islam) or even against Jewish seculars, which significantly impacts their daily life (Cohen & Susser, 2000; Cohn, 2002), such as that public transportation no operates in Shabbat and Jewish holidays in Israel (Arutz Sheva, 2017) even not from airports, while roads near synagogues are closed for cars entry, and Jewish villages are even entirely closed during the Shabbat. Even non-kosher food is not available at most supermarkets in Israel (Heiman et al., 2019), while in Jewish religious cities even stores and gas stations are closed during the Shabbat (Lis, 2018; Times of Israel, 2018). Notably, there are countries that have a combination of two regime types, such as Saudi Arabia that has a combination of absolute monarchy and an Islamic religious regime (Buchan, 2015). Thereby, in Islamic religious regimes, the religious coercion is even worse, such as in the case of Saudi Arabia and Iran (Buchan, 2015), still, paradoxically, the Islam restrictions in Saudi Arabia are more rigid than in Iran. In Saudi Arabia, non-Islam houses of worship are forbidden including forbidden to practice in non-Islam worship (USCIRF, 2017), while a person may even risk in a death penalty in Saudi Arabia for smuggling and possessing non-Islam holy books (e.g. Bibles) (Smith, 2014). However, in Iran, non-Islam houses of worship are permitted (e.g. churches and synagogues) including practising in non-Islam worship, while the Iranian government even reserves seats in the Iranian parliament for recognized religious minorities, such as Christianity, Judaism, and the Sunni branch (Brock & Levers, 2007). Moreover, in Saudi Arabia women must wear a Burqa (full cover of the body and face), while Iranian women must wear only a hijab (only cover of the head) (Koo & Han, 2018). Besides, Saudi Arabia has only Muslim citizens, so Christian foreign workers cannot even get a permanent residence permit nor apply for the citizenship of Saudi Arabia, while Iran has non-Muslim citizens, such as Christian, Zoroastrians and Jews (CIA, 2021). Importantly, in Saudi Arabia, there are no political rights because it is an absolute monarchy, while in Iran a free general election takes place for the President of Iran with a limited of a maximum of two terms (four years each term), yet the president of Iran should be approved by the religious supreme leader and act according to his guidance (Iran Parliament, 2021; UNIBE, 2020). Given that, Saudi Arabia may be considered as a ‘monarchy religious regime’, while Iran may be considered as a ‘partial democracy religious regime’ because Iran grants some political and religious rights to its citizens according to its constitution ̶ ‘Theocratic and Democratic Elements’ from 1979 (Iran Parliament, 2021; UNIBE, 2020). In spite of the religious coercion that exists in religious regimes, paradoxically, religious regimes have a lower risk for regime transformation, especially in countries in which the religious tradition has been rooted in the country for hundreds of years, such as in Iran (Beeman, 1986) and Saudi Arabia. In the case of Iran, the religious regime stability (over 40 years since the revolution in 1979) may be also explained by the bad memory of the previous absolute monarchy of the Shah (Kurzman, 2009; Takeya, 2021). The bad memory of the SAVAK-secret police of the Shah that tortured and executed many Shah opponents (Baraheni, 1976) may still impact the political arena in Iran. In other words, it can be argued that from the standpoint of the Iranian people, the Islamic religious regime that runs as partial democracy is much better than what it was under the Shah regime. Considering the above, if a country has religious coercion that significantly impacts the daily life of the religious minorities and seculars, then the country should be considered as a religious regime. Besides, in a religious regime, the constitution and laws give priority to the dominant religion over other religions, such as the new ‘Nationality Bill’ of Israel that defines Israel as a ‘Nation-State of the Jewish People’ (The Knesset, 2019), despite that this law contradicts the principle of the ‘Israeli Declaration of Independence’ that equal rights should be given to all Israeli citizens, regardless of their religion (The Knesset, 2021).  Hence, the most important indication for regime transformation to a religious regime is if the regime passed amendments to the constitution or new laws that give priority to the dominant religion by creating de-facto religious coercion against other religious minorities and seculars in a way that impacts their daily life.

Military Regime. In a military regime (Agyeman-Duah, 1990; Napolitano, 2018; Schneider, 2011), a military officer rises to power following a military coup (Agyeman-Duah, 1990; Belkin & Schofer, 2003; Luttwak, 2016; Londregan & Poole, 1990; Shipley, 2018; Sombatpoonsiri, 2017; Tendi, 2020; Thyne & Powell, 2016) without general election or elite election, such as the military regimes in Africa (Agyeman-Duah, 1990; Tendi, 2020). Hence, in a military regime, military officers manage forcibly the country affairs without any respect for human rights (Kingsley, 2014; Rutherford, 2018) or even without a decent court system that respect justice, such as the fast-secret legal proceeding that carried out against the ousted leader Aung San following the military coup in Myanmar in 2021 (Beech, 2021). Notably, there is a difference between a temporary military regime and a permanent military regime. A temporary military regime can be conducted in a situation of ‘State of Emergency’ for a limited period (Fassin & Pandolfi, 2010), while a permanent military regime is established following a military coup or in occupied territories, such as the permanent Israeli military regime that controls occupied Palestine through Israeli soldiers and the Israeli military court over more than 50 years since 1967, so it considered as the longest military occupation regime worldwide (Hajjar, 2005; Pelleg-Sryck, 2011; Roberts, 1990). Nevertheless, a temporary military regime following ‘State of Emergency’ can transform into a permanent military regime if it is run too long without preserving human rights and civil rights, such as the case of Turkey that following the failed attempt coup in 2016, over two years Turkey conducted unprecedented purges against military officers, civil servants, and private citizens under formal ‘State of Emergency’ (Kenner, 2017). Still, when the formal ‘State of Emergency’ ends, then it has replaced with new laws that gave the President of Turkey, Erdogan the power to continue running de-facto ‘State of Emergency’ including purges (Keller et al., 2016; Kenner, 2017; Kynyon, 2018). Considering the above, a military regime is the most problematic regime type among repressive regimes in terms of political risk because of the reason that all the power is in the hand of military officers. Importantly, if a regime is currently a democracy, but suffered in the past from a military coup or ruled by a military junta, then exists the risk for reversal transformation to a military regime, such as the case of Myanmar that was ruled by a military junta from 1962 until 2011, and then it functioned as a democracy until the military coup in 2021 that reverse the country to a military regime (Egreteau, 2016; Devi, 2014; Huang, 2013; Mahtani & Lynn, 2021). Notwithstanding, as the time passed since the last military coup/military regime, then the risk for reversal transformation to a military regime is reduced.

Layer II – Level of Freedom of Regime Type: Full Democratic Regime vs. Partial Democratic Regime vs. Repressive Regime

The second layer of regime type is based on the level of freedom. In other words, regardless of the characteristics of each regime type outlined above, each regime can have a different level of freedom namely, full freedom or partial freedom or repressive (no freedom). At the terminology level, full freedom is similar to a full democratic regime, partial freedom is similar to a partial democratic regime and repressive is similar to a repressive regime. Nevertheless, democracies are usually considered as a full democratic regime or as a partial democratic regime, while religious regimes are usually considered as a partial democracy or as a repressive regime. Conversely, communism, absolute monarchy and military regimes are usually considered repressive regimes. Nevertheless, when a regime undergoes a transformation, either from a democracy to a repressive regime, or vice versa, from a repressive regime to a democracy, then the formal status of the regime type may not represent the regime type of a country, such as the cases of Liechtenstein and Jordan that are formally considered as ‘democracy-constitutional monarchy’ regimes, but these countries are de-facto ‘partial democracy-absolute monarchy’ regimes (Al-Sharif, 2014; Langley, 2013). Therefore, a partial democracy can exist when a regime undergoes a transformation in both directions. Importantly, the level of freedom reflects a scale, yet it is possible to generalize the characteristics of a full democratic regime versus a partial democratic regime versus a repressive regime, as follows.

Full Democratic Regime. A full democratic regime is equivalent to a full freedom regime. The literature suggests that democracy with full-freedom should have the following characteristics (Altman & Perez-Linan, 2002; Beetham, 2004; Christiano, 2018; Dahl, 2020; Gould, 1990; Schmitter & Karl, 1991): Firstly, a full democracy should have a free general election without creating manipulation to change the election results. Besides, a full democracy should keep the political right to hold protests and strikes without protests repression (e.g. tear gas or water cannons) (Aytac et al., 2017) or without bureaucratic restrictions (e.g. not giving permission to protest) (Hovel, 2017) that de-facto prevents the right to demonstrate. Secondly, a full democracy should allow the freedom of opinion and expression, free press, freedom to establish labour unions and religious freedom. Thirdly, a full democratic regime should protect human rights, civilian rights, and property rights. Fourthly, a public administration in a full democracy should operate under the principles of transparency, comptroller mechanism, and limited terms for high-rank public office. Fifthly, in a full democracy exists ‘checks and balances’ through a separation of power between parliament, government and courts. In spite of the above, a full democracy can transform from partial democracy or even from a repressive regime, such as the republic revolution in Portugal that happened in 1974 when a military coup ended 50 years of an autocratic regime (Fishman, 2011), while a year later, in 1975, the first democratic general election was held in Portugal, which signalled the transformation of Portugal into a democratic regime (Rebelo Morais, 2020; Schmitter & Karl, 1991). However, one of the important indicators for strong full democracy is the time that has passed since the last transformation to full democracy. In other words, as time pass since the last transformation to full democracy, then the risk for reversal transformation is reduced. For example, a few East European countries were accepted as EU full members based on the assumption that they completed their transformation from a communist regime to full democracy, however, a few years later, has started a reversal transformation from a full democratic regime to a partial democratic regime, such as the case of Hungary and Poland (Baczynska, 2020; Mueller, 2014). Hence, previous regime types of a country and the period that passed since the last regime transformation may provide important indicators for the risk of regime transformation from a full democracy to partial democracy or worse to a repressive regime.

Repressive Regime. A repressive regime is equivalent to a regime without freedom. The literature includes various terms for repressive regimes, such as autocracy (Ang, 2018; Treisman, 2018; Tullock, 2012), dictatorship (Kendall-Taylor et al, 2020; Keremoglu & Weidmann, 2020; Kirchick, 2017; Schmitt, 2014; Wintrobe, 2000), totalitarianism (Gleason, 1997; Kamenka, 2017; Linz, 2000) and authoritarian (Ezrow & Frantz, 2011; Norris & Inglehart, 2019; Svolik, 2012; Von Soest & Grauvogel, 2017). Though all these terms represent regimes that restrict the rights of their citizens, either by a single leader (e.g. dictator) or by a group of leaders (e.g. Military junta). Hence, previous studies suggest that repressive regimes have the following characteristics (Ang, 2018; Gleason, 1997; Ezrow & Frantz, 2011; Kamenka, 2017; Kendall-Taylor et al, 2020; Kim & Kroeger, 2018; Kirchick, 2017; Linz, 2000; Norris & Inglehart, 2019; Schmitt, 2014; Svolik, 2012; Thyne & Powell, 2016; Treisman, 2018; Tullock, 2012; Von Soest & Grauvogel, 2017; Wintrobe, 2000): Firstly, an individual or a party or an elite political group has total power to manage the affairs of the country. Secondly, in a repressive regime, political pluralism is limited via restrictive laws that limit political parties, while opponents suffer from oppression and political persecution. Thirdly, a free general election does not take place, and even if it takes place, then it is not carried out democratically, and consequently, there is no change in leadership or government party. Besides, in many repressive regimes, the power is transferred from father to son or from the leader to a family member even if the regime is not an absolute monarchy, such as the leadership in Syria that was transferred from the father Hafez al-Assad to his son Bashar al-Assad (CNN, 2012), or as the case of Cuba that the leadership was transferred from Fidel Castro to his brother Raul Castro (Sullivan, 2007). Fourthly, decision-making is carried out by the leader and its loyal advisers or by the elite party, yet without ‘checks and balances’ nor transparency that exists in a full democracy. Fifthly, in a repressive regime, freedom rights are violated, particularly against opposition and journalism, while demonstrations, strikes and expressing opposition views are forbidden. Considering the above, a regime transformation from a democratic regime to a repressive regime can be the most chaotic transformation because it usually occurs via revolution or coup. For example, President Morsi was elected via the first historic democratic general election in Egypt that took place in 2012 (Al Jazeera, 2012), but a year later, Morsi was ousted via military coup by Sisi that served the Ministry of Defence under President Morsi (Wedeman et al., 2013). Following the coup, Sisi led the Rabaa massacre against hundreds of civilians that opposed the coup (Kingsley, 2014). Eventually, Sisi was elected as President of Egypt in 2014 via a controversial election, and since then Sisi rules Egypt as an autocratic leader (Rutherford, 2018; Fayazi & Dehshiri, 2020). Considering that, the expectation that a regime transformation to a repressive regime will increase the political risk, especially when it occurs following a coup. 

Partial Democratic Regime. A partial democracy (Robinson, 2003; Sznajder & Roniger, 2003) is equivalent to a partly free regime. The literature mainly distinguishes between the characteristics of a full democratic regime versus a repressive regime as discussed above, despite that most regimes worldwide are de-facto considered as a partial democracy. According to Freedom House which monitors the degree of civil liberties and political rights worldwide, in 2020, 83 countries were considered as free regimes, 63 countries as partly free regimes, while 49 countries as not free regimes (Freedom House, 2020). Nonetheless, if we look in-depth at the rank of freedom house, then only 56 countries may be considered as full democratic regimes (85-100 points), while 88 countries may be considered as partial democratic regimes (35-85 points) (Freedom House, 2020). Thus, most of the countries worldwide are partial democratic regimes, rather than full democratic regimes. For example, according to house freedom, in 2020, Israel under Netanyahu has 76 points, while Brazil under Bolsonarmo has 75 points, so despite they being considered free regimes (Freedom House, 2020), they are de-facto partial democratic regimes and not full democratic regimes. Considering the above, a partial democratic regime is the common regime type that exists today worldwide, rather than a full democratic regime, or vice versa, a repressive regime. Importantly, a partial democracy can transform from a full democracy to a partial democracy, or vice versa, from a repressive regime to a partial democratic regime. The transformation from a full democratic regime to a partial democratic regime mainly occurs via changing a constitution or laws by a leader to get more power, such as the amendment that was done to the Russian constitution in 2020 that cancel the limit of four terms to allow Putin to stay as the president of Russia for six terms instead of four terms until 2036, while an additional amendment gives Putin the right to dismiss judges (Osborn & Balmforth, 2020). That is mean that Putin may serve as the president of Russia for over 36 years, from 2000 until 2036 with the ability to control the Russian court system, thereby, it signals the regime transformation of Russia. Even intention to cancel the limited terms of PM/President may indicate that the regime has started the transformation to partial democracy. For example, President Trump during his tenure has started to mull about the third term of the presidency under the argument that he is ‘entitled to it’ (Agerholm, 2018; Lord, 2019; Solender, 2020). Trump assumed that he would win the second term, so even in his first term, he started to plan how he will stay as the president of the USA longer than two terms. Besides, President Trump acted with his family members like ‘royal family’ by giving them significant roles, access to classified materials, and participating at high-rank meetings without the proper proceeding that requires from federal employees (Cassidy, 2018; CBC News, 2019; Sutton, 2017), while in his last hours as president, he even gave pardon for the father of his son in law, Kushner (MercoPress, 2020). Even takeovers on parliament by a leader may indicate a transformation from a full democracy to a partial democracy, such as the trying of PM Boris Johnson to shut down the UK House of Common for a long period to prevent MPs to pass a resolution against his government (Brown, 2019). This attempt was blocked by the UK supreme court that ruled that the suspension of parliament by PM Boris Johnson was unlawful (Shirbon & Holden, 2019). However, supreme courts in democracies are not always strong to block problematic leaders, so democracies are not always safe from regime transformation via appealing to a supreme court, such as the case of the Israeli supreme court that rejected an appeal against PM of Netanyahu that was given on the ground that Netanyahu can’t serve as a PM of Israel when he has a trial on crimes of bribe and breach of trust (Reuters, 2020), regardless of the convicted of his wife, Sara Netanyahu, that pleaded guilty in misusing public funds (The Hindu, 2019). Usually, in a full democracy, if a leader has a political scandal, then it immediately leads to impeachment or resignation, such as the case of the former president of South Korea, Park Geun-hye that impeached immediately when the abuse of power was revealed (Sang-Hun, 2016). Even, in Israel, in the pre-Netanyahu era, Olmert resigned as a PM of Israel when the investigation started and even before he was been formally indicted on fraud and breach of trust (BBC, 2012; Heller, 2008), while PM Rabin even resigned in his first term in 1977 due to a minor political scandal when it was revealed that he and his wife held foreign bank accounts in breach of Israeli law that was in that period (JTA, 1977). Thus, the new norm in Israel that PM can serve during a bribe trial may signal that the regime in Israel transformed from a full democracy to a partial democracy, regardless of the religious correction that is typical to a religious regime (Akerman, 2014). In light of the above, in partial democracy, the leader gets more power via changing the constitution and laws, especially regarding the ability to stay at the office of PM/President without limited terms. Hence, democracies that have a limited single term for PM/President like South Korea (Korea Assembly, 2012) or a maximum of two limited terms like the USA may have less risk for a regime transformation to a partial democracy compared to democracies without limited terms for PM/President. Nevertheless, any planning to cancel the limited terms for PM/President or to extend them (Solender, 2020) may signal that the full democracy has started the regime transformation to a partial democracy (Agerholm, 2018). Even though, a strong supreme court should be in a democracy to protect the trying to transform the regime from a full democracy to a partial democracy (Shirbon & Holden, 2019).

A Regime Type as a Crucial Location Factor of FDI Inward: Political Risk of Regime Transformation

The regime type and its level of freedom alongside its likelihood for a regime transformation at the country level affect the political risk of FDI inward in host countries. The literature suggests that democracies positively influence FDI inward (Asiedu & Lien, 2011; Escriba-Folch, 2017; Jensen, 2003, 2008; Li & Resnick, 2003), especially in the service sector, and in finance, insurance, and information activities, in particular (Kucera & Principi, 2014). However, democracy has less influence on FDI Inward in oil and minerals countries (Asiedu & Lien, 2011) and even a negative effect in mining, oil, and gas industries (Kucera & Principi, 2014). Doytch & Eren (2012) found that democracy positively impacts FDI in the agricultural and manufacturing sectors in Eastern Europe and Central Asia. Malikane & Chitambara (2017) found that democracy positively influences spillover from FDI Inward.  Even Yang (2007) found that democracy impacts positively a higher level of per capita FDI in developing countries but does not influence the level of FDI nor FDI as a ratio to GDP. However, Li (2009) found that democracies encourage FDI when leaders face little political constraint yet with frequent leadership turnover, while autocracies encourage FDI when leaders face high political constraint yet stay in power for long.

The literature also suggests that repressive regimes are generally risky for FDI (Bastiaens, 2016; Francois et al., 2020; Tomashevskiy, 2017). Although, Bastiaens (2016) found that authoritarian countries can reduce the risk for FDI if they sign on international investment treaties, especially in cases that the country allows some degree of public policy deliberation. Bak & Moon (2016) even found that FDI reduced authoritarian leadership failure and even the likelihood of a coup by using FDI long-term to appease elite dissents and to buy off potential elite challengers. Tomashevskiy (2017) also found that increasing FDI in repressive regimes reduce the risk for a coup because paradoxically, investors send a larger amount of FDI to increase the peaceful patronage when the risk for a coup is high. Still, the study showed that an increase in FDI in the mining, oil and gas sectors may increase the likelihood of a coup (Tomashevskiy, 2017). Moon (2019) found that autocratic countries with legislatures attract more FDI than other autocratic countries. Francois et al. (2020) found that educated dictators with business experience attract more FDI compared to other dictators.

However, the literature suggests that exists a significant difference in the political risk for FDI Inward between communist regime versus absolute monarchy regime versus religious regime versus military regime, as follows. Firstly, the literature suggests that the remaining communist regimes worldwide are relatively politicly stable and even with a long positive trend of attracting FDI Inward, especially in China (Chen et al., 2020; Dullien, 2005; Fung et al., 2004; Jiang et al., 2013; Lau & Bruton, 2008), and Vietnam (Athukorala & Tien, 2012; Freeman, 2001; Xuan & King, 2008). Nonetheless, Cuba is set apart from other communist regimes in relation to FDI Inward because of the USA embargo (Gordon, 2012; Walsh, 2017). Importantly, despite that communist regimes lack political and freedom rights, paradoxically, the likelihood for a democratic revolution in the remaining communist regimes is significantly low. Nevertheless, these communist regimes may transform into a mixed economy in the long run, yet without a significant change in the communist political ideology. Given that, the expectation that the risk for FDI in communist regimes is low compared to other repressive regimes, despite the controversial communism ideology regarding political rights. Secondly, a religious regime type may have a mixed effect on FDI (Helble, 2007), yet the risk for foreign investors is low if the dominant religion is relatively big compared to other religions and secular groups in a natural way without religious coercion. From the FDI perspective, religion has a huge impact on the lifestyle, and consumption habits of its believers (Shyan Fam et al., 2004; Wach, 2016; Woodhead et al., 2016), so religious diversity plays a significant role in attracting FDI Inward (Dolansky & Alon, 2006). Thus, a lack of religious diversity amid religious coercion (Pinkkus & Meyer, 2008) may impact the scope of FDI Inward, especially regarding FDI market-seeking. Besides, the values and rules of the dominant religion influence the management methods and practices, (Li, 2008) alongside the work habits (Shyan Fam et al., 2004), so MNEs are required to adapt their working rules, products, and services to the requirements of the dominant religion in the host country. Hence, religious coercion may have a negative impact on FDI in terms of scope and risk, especially if the share of other religious and scholars in the host country is relatively big. In other words, resistance to religious coercion may increase the risk for FDI because it may lead to regime transformation via secular revolution. However, in most religious regimes, the share of the dominant religion is naturally big, so the likelihood for a regime transformation is low, such as in the cases of Saudi-Arabia (officially 100% Muslims) and Iran (99.6% Muslims) (CIA, 2021). Besides, in the case of Iran, the combination of the Muslim majority along with a partial democracy even significantly reduce the motivation for a regime transformation via a ‘secular-democracy revolution’. However, the motivation for a regime transformation via ‘secular-democracy revolution’ may be higher in the case of a religious regime that the share of minorities religious and seculars is too big to ignore, such as the case of Israel that the religious coercive may push for a regime transformation from a ‘partial democracy-religious regime’ to a ‘secular-full democratic regime’ because the share of Israeli Jewish religious among the total Israeli population is relatively small. More specifically, the share of Israeli non-Jewish religious is 25.7% (CIA, 2021), while the share of Israeli Jewish seculars (Hiloni) is 49% (Starr & Masci, 2016), so this share of 74.7% includes the Israeli non-Jewish religious and the Israeli Jewish seculars has the potential to create a regime transformation in Israel via ‘secular coalition’. In light of the above, in a religious regime exists a minor risk for FDI if the share of the dominant religion is relatively big. Conversely, a religious regime via religious coercion may restrict the scope of FDI and even increase its risk if the share of the minorities’ religious and seculars is relatively big to ignore in the host country. Thirdly, an absolute monarchy regime has a higher risk for FDI compared to a communist regime and a religious regime because an absolute monarchy regime is doomed for a regime transformation (Hoffman, 2015) either via transformation of constitutional monarchy (Barker, 1944; Gilmour, 1985) or via transformation of ‘republic revolution’ as happened to most of the absolute monarchy regimes in the last three centuries since the French revolution (Livesey, 2001). Nonetheless, a regime transformation can even occur via a ‘monarchy coup’ by another monarchy family member, mainly via assassination (Hoffman, 2015), such as what happened in Saudi Arabia when King Saud was forcibly ousted from the throne by his brother King Faisal that years later assassinated by his nephew (Wynbrandt, 2010). Nevertheless, FDI Inward has the potential for high profits in an absolute monarchy regime (Elimam, 2017; Shotar, 2005; Tabash & Dhankar, 2014) because of the lack of bureaucracy and competition that is typical for tenders in democracies. Still, it may involve a high risk for FDI, especially in a kingdom with a history of a ‘monarchy coup’, especially if it happened in the near past. Fourthly, a military regime is the riskier regime type for FDI Inward compared to other regime types, yet paradoxically, a military regime can provide the highest profits among all regime types because of the ability to get exclusive contracts based on bribe and corruption (Cheung et al., 2012; Gilbert & Sharman, 2016), especially in military regimes in Africa (Jalil et al., 2016; Teixeira & Guimaraes, 2015). Thereby, ethical, and illegal problems may increase the risk for FDI in military regimes (Holliday, 2005) due to the ‘norm of bribery’ (Habib & Zurawicki, 2002; Weiss, 2008), especially in Africa even in partially democratic regimes (Kochan, 2013; Nebehay, 2021). Besides, FDI in a military regime may also involve a ‘coup risk’ (Tomashevskiy, 2017) that can be carried out by a rival dictator or a military junta (Mahtani & Lynn, 2021).  Despite the risks outlined above, many MNEs operate on a large scale in military regimes (Oneal., 1994; Tuman & Emmert, 2004) because of the ability to obtain exclusive contracts with high profits. Nevertheless, military regimes can change the laws, regulations, permissions, and restrictions overnight, and even cancelling licenses and contracts, which increases the risk for FDI due to concern that an exclusive contract or license will not survive for long in case of a regime transformation, especially via a coup by a rival dictator.

In light of the above, a regime type as a location factor of FDI Inward leads to a high correlation between risk and profitability. More specifically, a high risk of FDI is associated with the high profitability of FDI in a repressive regime, as well as in a partially democratic regime. Conversely, a low risk of FDI is associated with the low profitability of FDI in a full democratic regime. In other words, an FDI contract in a full democratic regime is based on competition to reduce prices, which decreases the profits, but at the same time, it reduces the risk for foreign investors due to the certainty of the trustworthy contract. Conversely, an FDI contract in a repressive regime is based in some cases on bribery and corruption, especially in military regimes, which increases the profits, but at the same time, it increases the risk for FDI due to the fear of chaotic regime transformation, especially via a coup. 

Conclusions

This study explored the regime type as a location factor of FDI to predict the political risk for FDI Inward in a host country. Although, the FDI literature mainly focuses on political instability as a location factor of FDI over a regime type. However, political instability as a location factor of FDI allows knowing about the deterioration of political conditions (e.g. Internal and external conflicts) that were already occurred in the past in a host country (Aguiar et al., 2012; Burger et al., 2016; Godinez & Liu, 2018; Rafat & Farahani, 2019; Rashid et al., 2017; Rozen-Bakher, 2017; Samimi et al., 2011; Sethi et al., 2003), while a regime type as a location factor of FDI allows predicting the political risk for FDI that may occur in the FUTURE due to a regime transformation (Bak & Moon, 2016; Tomashevskiy,2017). Thereby, each regime type has different characteristics, level of freedom, and likelihood for a regime transformation, which may lead to a different level of political risk for FDI Inward. A regime transformation usually occurs suddenly without any pre-warning or visible indications, especially in cases of a military coup (Elumami & Laessing, 2019; Luttwak, 2016; Mahtani & Lynn, 2021; Sombatpoonsiri, 2017; Stoakes & Safi, 2021; Tendi, 2020; Thyne & Powell, 2016), and assassination (Hoffman, 2015).  Though, even if exist signs of political unrest in case of revolution (Fishman, 2011 Takeyh, 2021), then still a regime transformation may happen suddenly without sufficient time for MNEs to adjust to the sudden change. Thus, from the viewpoint of decision-makers that deal with conducting FDI inward, the foremost factor is the risk of investment in the host country, especially due to a chaotic regime transformation that can lead to a total loss of investment, such as what happened to American firms during the communist revolution of Fiddle Castro in Cuba that led to a nationalization of assets of American firms (Domke, 1961).

To address the research objective, the study investigated the regime type at two layers of analysis namely, the characteristics of each regime type and its level of freedom to reveal the likelihood for a regime transformation that may risk FDI Inward. Hence, the study explored five regime types: democratic regime, communist regime, absolute monarchy regime, religious regime, and a military regime, while also investigating the implication of level of freedom via comparing full democratic regime, partially democratic regime and a repressive regime. 

The analysis of the study indicates that exists significant differences between regime types examined in the study. Firstly, a democratic regime is less risky for FDI among all types of regimes yet exists a critical difference between a full democratic regime and a partially democratic regime regarding the political risk of FDI Inward. The common belief that a democratic regime has a low risk for a regime transformation, yet history has taught us that the worst dictator in modern history, Hitler, was raised to power not following a military coup or a revolution but through a long legal process that step by step overthrow the democracy of the Weimar Republic until he became a dictator when he succeeded to neutralise the parliament via a tactic of ‘state of emergency’ (Abel, 1986). Hence, a transformation from a full democratic regime to a partial democratic regime or even worse to a repressive regime does not occur ‘overnight’ as happened in a military coup but through legal manoeuvres via changing the constitution and laws to allow the dictator to stay permanently as the ruler of the country. That is done via cancelling the limited terms of the head of state alongside getting more power to choose, or vice versa, to remove high-rank public officers (Osborn & Balmforth, 2020). Given that, a full democratic regime that has a limited single term for the head of state (Korea Assembly, 2012) or a maximum of two limited terms (Lord, 2019) is less risky for a regime transformation to a partial democratic regime or worse to a repressive regime. Though any planning to cancel the limited terms for the head of state (Solender, 2020) may signal that the full democracy has started the transformation to a partial democracy (Agerholm, 2018). Nevertheless, a strong supreme court can be the guardian of democracy to prevent any trying to transform the regime from a full democracy to a partial democracy (Shirbon & Holden, 2019). All the same, one of the vital indicators for a strong full democracy is the time that passed since the last transformation to a full democratic regime. Secondly, a communist regime may also have a low political risk for FDI Inward due to the stronghold of the communist party in the remaining regimes. Hence, paradoxically, the likelihood for a regime transformation in the remaining communist regimes worldwide is relatively low, particularly via a democratic revolution, despite the lack of political rights in communism. That particularly applies to China which may be ‘too big to fall’. Nevertheless, the remain communist regimes may transform into a mixed economy in the long run, yet without a significant change in the communist political ideology. Thirdly, a region should be considered as a religious regime if the religious coercion significantly impacts the daily life of other religions and seculars through constitution and laws that give priority to the dominant religion. However, the political risk for FDI in a religious regime depends on the share of the dominant religion compared to the share of minorities religious and seculars. Thereby, the risk for foreign investors is low if the dominant religion is relatively big compared to other religions and secular groups in a natural way without religious coercion. Conversely, if the share of minorities’ religious and seculars is too big to ignore, then it may lead to resistance to religious coercion that may end in a regime transformation, resulting in political risk for FDI. Fourthly, an absolute monarchy regime is doomed for a regime transformation (Hoffman, 2015) via a transformation of constitutional monarchy (Barker, 1944; Gilmour, 1985), or republic revolution, or even via a ‘monarchy coup’ by another member of the royal family (Wynbrandt, 2010). However, FDI Inward has the potential for high profits in an absolute monarchy regime (Elimam, 2017; Tabash & Dhankar, 2014), but at the same time, it may involve a high political risk for FDI, particularly in a kingdom with a history of a ‘monarchy coup’, especially if it happened in the near past. Fifthly, a military regime is the riskier regime type for FDI Inward due to lack of an adequate justice system (Beech, 2021), yet paradoxically, a military regime can provide the highest profits because of the ability to get exclusive contracts based on bribes and corruption (Cheung et al., 2012; Gilbert & Sharman, 2016). Thus, FDI in a military regime may involve a ‘bribe risk’ (Cheung et al., 2012; Gilbert & Sharman, 2016; Teixeira & Guimaraes, 2015; Weiss, 2008) due to corruption norm in this kind of regime, as well as a ‘coup risk’ (Tomashevskiy, 2017) that can be carried out by a rival dictator or a military junta (Mahtani & Lynn, 2021), which may lead to a cancellation of FDI exclusive contracts that were made by the previous military ruler. Nevertheless, even, if a regime is currently a democracy, but suffered in the past from a military coup or ruled by a military dictator or a military junta, then exists the risk for a reversal regime transformation to a military regime (Devi, 2014; Mahtani & Lynn, 2021). Still, as time passed since the last military regime, then the risk is reduced for a reversal regime transformation to a military regime.

The study concluded that a high risk of FDI is associated with the high profitability of FDI mainly in repressive regimes, especially in military regimes and absolute monarchy regimes. Conversely, a low risk of FDI is associated with low profitability of FDI mainly in a full democratic regime. However, the study emphasized the need to strike a balance between risky regime type and high profits to reduce the political risk of FDI Inward due to the potential of chaotic regime transformation that may ignore the obligation to FDI contracts, or worse, it may lead to the nationalization of MNEs’ assets.   

References

Abel, T. (1986). Why Hitler came into power. Harvard University Press.

Achen, C. H., & Bartels, L. M. (2016). Democracy for realists. Princeton University Press.

Agerholm, H. (2018 February 5). America falls short of being a full democracy for second year running, report finds. INDEPENDENT, https://www.independent.co.uk/news/world/americas/america-democracy-rated-donald-trump-not-fully-democratic-us-president-report-the-economist-a8195121.html

Aguiar, S., Aguiar-Conraria, L., Gulamhussen, M.A., & Magalhaes, P.C. (2012). Foreign Direct Investment and home-country political risk: The case of Brazil. Latin American Research Review, 47, 144–165.

Agyeman-Duah, B. (1990). Military Coups, Regime Change, and Interstate Conflicts in West Africa. Armed Forces & Society16(4), 547-570.

Ahdar, R. (2012). Regulating Religious Coercion. Stan. JCR & CL8, 215.

Akerman, L. (2014 May 5). Is Israel a True Democracy? Jerusalem Post, https://www.jpost.com/Opinion/Op-Ed-Contributors/Is-Israel-a-true-democracy-352445

Al Jazeera. (2012 June 24). Celebration in Egypt as Morsi declared winner. Al Jazeera, https://www.aljazeera.com/news/2012/6/24/celebration-in-egypt-as-morsi-declared-winner

Alaoudh, A. (2017 July 19). Saudi Arabia’s crown prince is taking the kingdom back to the Dark Ages. Washington Post, https://www.washingtonpost.com/news/global-opinions/wp/2018/07/19/saudi-arabias-crown-prince-is-taking-the-kingdom-back-to-the-dark-ages/?noredirect=on&utm_term=.11d789efbebe

Al-Sharif, O. (2014 August 2014).  Jordan's king pushes to expand military, intelligence authority. Al-Monitor, http://www.al-monitor.com/pulse/originals/2014/08/jordan-king-constitution-amendments.html

Altman, D., & Pérez-Liñán, A. (2002). Assessing the quality of democracy: Freedom, competitiveness and participation in eighteen Latin American countries. Democratization9(2), 85-100.

Andeweg, R.B. and G.A. Irwin (2002) Governance and Politics of the NetherlandsBasingstoke: MacMillan.

Andreas, P. (2005). Criminalizing consequences of sanctions: Embargo busting and its legacy. International Studies Quarterly, 49(2), 335-360.

Ang, Y. Y. (2018). Autocracy with Chinese characteristics: Beijing's Behind-the-Scenes reforms. Foreign Aff.97, 39.

Arutz Sheva. (2017 June 15). Yesh Atid pushes for public transportation on Shabbat. Arutz Sheva, https://www.israelnationalnews.com/News/News.aspx/231109

Ash, R., Ferdinand, P., Hook, B., & Porter, R. (Eds.). (2000). Hong Kong in transition: the handover years. Springer.

Asiedu, E., & Lien, D. (2011). Democracy, foreign direct investment and natural resources. Journal of international economics84(1), 99-111.

Athukorala, P. C., & Tien, T. Q. (2012). Foreign direct investment in industrial transition: the experience of Vietnam. Journal of the Asia Pacific Economy17(3), 446-463.

Ayoub, P., & Paternotte, D. (2019). Europe and LGBT rights: A conflicted relationship. Bosia, M., McEvoy, S., & Rahman, M. The Oxford handbook of global LGBT and sexual diversity politics. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press. Find this resource.

Aytaç, S. E., Schiumerini, L., & Stokes, S. (2017). Protests and repression in new democracies. Perspectives on Politics15(1), 62.

Baczynska, G. (2020 September 30). EU slams Poland, Hungary as cash-for-democracy fight heats up. Reuters. https://uk.reuters.com/article/uk-eu-democracy/eu-criticises-poland-hungary-in-first-democracy-report-idUKKBN26L1FH

Bak, D., & Moon, C. (2016). Foreign direct investment and authoritarian stability. Comparative Political Studies49(14), 1998-2037.

Bano, S., Zhao, Y., Ahmad, A., Wang, S., & Liu, Y. (2019). Why did FDI inflows of Pakistan decline? From the perspective of terrorism, energy shortage, financial instability, and political instability. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade55(1), 90-104.

Baraheni, R. (1976 October 28). Terror in Iran. The New York Review of Books.

Barbieri, K., & Levy, J. S. (1999). Sleeping with the enemy: The impact of war on trade. Journal of peace research, 36(4), 463-479.

Barker, E. (1944). British constitutional monarchy. Oxford University Press.

Barr, N. (2020). Economics of the welfare state. Oxford University Press, USA.

Bastiaens, I. (2016). The politics of foreign direct investment in repressive regimes. International Interactions, 42(1), 140-171.

BBC. (2012 January 5). Ehud Olmert: Corruption allegations. BBC, https://web.archive.org/web/20120105181216/http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/world-middle-east-16426018

Beech, H. (2021 February 16). Trial for Aung San Suu Kyi Begins in Secret. New York Times, https://www.nytimes.com/2021/02/16/world/asia/myanmar-trial-aung-san-suu-kyi.html

Beeman, W. O. (1986). Iran's Religious Regime: What Makes It Tick? Will It Ever Run Down?. The ANNALS of the American Academy of Political and Social Science483(1), 73-83.

Beetham, D. (2004). The quality of democracy: Freedom as the foundation. Journal of Democracy15(4), 61-75.

Belkin, A., & Schofer, E. (2003). Toward a structural understanding of coup risk. Journal of conflict resolution47(5), 594-620.

Berman, S., & Snegovaya, M. (2019). Populism and the decline of social democracy. Journal of Democracy30(3), 5-19.

Bhardwaj, S. (2018). Problems Of Unemployment In India And Its Solutions. Deliberative Research37(1), 55-58.

Blum, J. (2017). The end of the old order in rural Europe. Princeton University Press.

Bouët, A., & Laborde, D. (2018). US trade wars in the twenty‐first century with emerging countries: Make America and its partners lose again. The World Economy, 41(9), 2276-2319.

Brancati, D. (2016). Democracy protests. Cambridge University Press.

Brecher, M., & Geist, B. (1980). Decisions in crisis: Israel, 1967 and 1973 (Vol. 1). Univ of California Press.

Brock, C., & Levers, L. Z. (Eds.). (2007). Aspects of Education in the Middle East and Africa. Symposium Books Ltd.

Brødsgaard, K. E., & Yongnian, Z. (Eds.). (2006). The Chinese Communist Party in Reform. Routledge.

Brown, L. (2019 September 9). Boris Johnson to shut down Parliament amid Brexit fight. New York Post, https://nypost.com/2019/09/09/boris-johnson-to-shut-down-parliament-amid-brexit-fight/

Brus, W., & Laski, K. (1991). From Marx to the market: Socialism in search of an economic system. OUP Catalogue.

Buchan, J. (2015). Secular and religious opposition in Saudi Arabia. In State, Society and Economy in Saudi Arabia (RLE Saudi Arabia) (pp. 108-126). Routledge.

Burger, M., Ianchovichina, E., & Rijkers, B. (2016). Risky business: Political instability and sectoral greenfield foreign direct investment in the Arab world. The World Bank Economic Review30(2), 306-331.

Burns, J. P., & Zhiren, Z. (2010). Performance management in the government of the People's Republic of China: accountability and control in the implementation of public policy. OECD Journal on Budgeting10(2), 1-28.

Busse, M. & Hefeker, C. (2007). Political Risk, Institutions and Foreign Direct Investment. European Journal of Political Economy, 27(2), 397–415.

Cai, Y. (2010). Collective resistance in China: Why popular protests succeed or fail. Stanford University Press.

Carson, R. L. (2017). Comparative Economic Systems: v. 2: Market and State in Economic Systems. Routledge.

Cassidy, J. (2018 March 2). Jared Kushner’s Conflicts of Interest Reach a Crisis Point. NewYorker, https://www.newyorker.com/news/our-columnists/jared-kushners-conflicts-of-interest-reach-a-crisis-point

CBC News. (2019 July 2). Ivanka Trump under scrutiny for G20 exchange. CBC News, https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=CQQ60a1yeh4

Chaudhry, K. A. (1991). On the way to market: economic liberalization and Iraq's invasion of Kuwait. Middle East Report, 14-23.

Chen, J., Zhan, W., Tong, Z., & Kumar, V. (2020). The effect of inward FDI on outward FDI over time in China: A contingent and dynamic perspective. International Business Review29(5), 101734.

Cheung, G. K. W. (2009). Hong Kong's Watershed: The 1967 Riots (Vol. 1). Hong Kong University Press.

Cheung, Y. L., Rau, P. R., & Stouraitis, A. (2012). How much do firms pay as bribes and what benefits do they get? Evidence from corruption cases worldwide (No. w17981). National Bureau of Economic Research.

Christiano, T. (2018). The rule of the many: Fundamental issues in democratic theory. Routledge.

CIA. (2021). The World Factbook. Central Intelligence Agency, https://www.cia.gov/the-world-factbook/countries/

CNN. (2012 December 06). Bashar al-Assad Fast Facts. CNN, https://edition.cnn.com/2012/12/06/world/meast/bashar-al-assad---fast-facts/index.html

Cohen, A., & Susser, B. (2000). Israel and the politics of Jewish identity: The secular-religious impasse. JHU Press.

Cohen-Almagor, R. (2017). The Monopoly of Jewish Orthodoxy in Israel and Its Effects on the Governance of Religious Diversity. The Problem of Religious Diversity (Edinburgh: Edinburgh University Press, 2017), 250-272.

Cohn, H. H. (2002). Religious freedom and religious coercion in the state of Israel. Human Rights Review3(2), 3-35.

Cooke, W.N. (2001). The effects of labour costs and workplace constraints on foreign direct investment among highly industrialized countries. International Journal of Human Resource Management, 12 (5), 697-716.

Dahl, R. A. (2020). On democracy. Yale university press.

Dallin, A. (1992). Causes of the Collapse of the USSR. Post-Soviet Affairs, 8(4), 279-302.

Datt, G., Ravallion, M., & Murgai, R. (2020). Poverty and growth in India over six decades. American Journal of Agricultural Economics102(1), 4-27.

De Nevers, R. (1993). Democratization and ethnic conflict. Survival, 35(2), 31-48.

De Vries, R. E. (2002). Ethnic tension in paradise: explaining ethnic supremacy aspirations in Fiji. International Journal of Intercultural Relations, 26(3), 311-327.

Della Porta, D. (2020). Protests as critical junctures: Some reflections towards a momentous approach to social movements. Social Movement Studies, 19(5-6), 556-575.

Devi, K. S. (2014). Myanmar under the military rule 1962-1988. International Research Journal of Social Sciences3(10), 46-50.

Dolansky, E., & Alon, I. (2008). Religious freedom, religious diversity, and Japanese foreign direct investment. Research in International Business and Finance22(1), 29-39.

Domke, M. (1961). Foreign Nationalizations: Some aspects of contemporary international law. Am. j. Int'l L.55, 585.

Driessen, M. D. (2014). Regime type, religion-state arrangements, and religious markets in the Muslim world. Sociology of Religion75(3), 367-394.

Dullien, S. (2005). FDI in China: trends and macroeconomic challenges. UNCTAD (2005) China in a Globalizing World, 125-54.

Dunleavy, P. (1987). Theories of the state: The politics of liberal democracy. Macmillan International Higher Education.

Dunning, J.H. & Lundan, S.M. (2008). Multinational Enterprises and the Global Economy. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

Egreteau, R. (2016). Caretaking democratization: The military and political change in Myanmar. Hurst & Co..

Elimam, H. (2017). Determinants of foreign direct investment in Saudi Arabia: A review. International Journal of Economics and Finance9(7), 222-227.

Elumami, A., & Laessing, U. (2019 April 15). U.N. Libya envoy says Haftar made coup attempt with advance on Tripoli. Reuters, https://uk.reuters.com/article/uk-libya-security/u-n-libya-envoy-says-haftar-made-coup-attempt-with-advance-on-tripoli-idUKKCN1RR1NH

Enders, W., & Sandler, T. (1996). Terrorism and foreign direct investment in Spain and Greece. Kyklos,49, 331–352.

Engels, F., & Marx, K. (2004). The communist manifesto. Broadview Press.

Escribà-Folch, A. (2017). Foreign direct investment and the risk of regime transition in autocracies. Democratization, 24(1), 61-80.

Esping-Andersen, G. (2017). Politics against markets: The social democratic road to power (Vol. 4877). Princeton University Press.

Ezrow, N. M., & Frantz, E. (2011). Dictators and dictatorships: Understanding repressive regimes and their leaders. Bloomsbury Publishing USA.

Faizullaev, A., & Cornut, J. (2017). Narrative practice in international politics and diplomacy: the case of the Crimean crisis. Journal of International Relations and Development20(3), 578-604.

Fassin, D., & Pandolfi, M. (2010). Contemporary states of emergency. The politics of military and humanitarian interventions. Zone Books.

Fayazi, S. A., & Dehshiri, M. (2020). US foreign policy towards Egypt after the Al-Sisi coup. Journal of Political Strategy4(14), 221-245.

Ferrari, A. (2018). Islam in Italy 2017: the year of the announced breakthrough?. Contemporary Italian Politics10(4), 421-433.

Fishman, R. M. (2011). Democratic practice after the revolution: the case of Portugal and beyond. Politics & Society39(2), 233-267.

Francois, A., Panel, S., & Weill, L. (2020). Educated dictators attract more foreign direct investment. Journal of Comparative Economics, 48(1), 37-55.

Freedom House. (2020). Freedom in the World Countries | Freedom House, Year 2020. freedomhouse.org. https://freedomhouse.org/explore-the-map?type=fiw&year=2020

Freeman, N. (2001). The Rise and Fall of Foreign Direct Investment in Laos, 1988‐2000. Post-Communist Economies13(1), 101-119.

Friedmann, Y. (2003). Tolerance and coercion in Islam: interfaith relations in the Muslim tradition. Cambridge University Press.

Fung, K. C., Iizaka, H., & Tong, S. Y. (2004). Foreign direct investment in China: Policy, recent trend and impact. Global Economic Review33(2), 99-130.

Gasiorowski, M. J. (1987). The 1953 coup d'etat in Iran. International Journal of Middle East Studies19(3), 261-286.

Gastanaga, J., Nugent, B. & Pashamova, B. (1998). Host country reforms and FDI inflows: How much difference do they make?. World Development, 26(7), 1299–1314.

Gilbert, J. A., & Sharman, J. C. (2016). Turning a blind eye to bribery: explaining failures to comply with the international anti-corruption regime. Political Studies64(1), 74-89.

Gillies, J., Leimann, J., & Peterson, R. (2002). Making a successful transition from a command to a market economy: The lessons from Estonia. Corporate governance: an international review, 10(3), 175-186.

Gilmour, D. (1985). The transformation of Spain: From Franco to the constitutional monarchy. Quartet Books Ltd.

Gleason, A. (1997). Totalitarianism: the inner history of the Cold War. Oxford University Press.

Globerman, S. & Shapiro, D. (1999). The impact of government policies on foreign direct investment: The Canadian experience. Journal of international business studies, 30(3), 513-532.

Globerman, S. & Shapiro, D. (2003). Governance infrastructure and US foreign direct investment. Journal of international business studies, 34(1), 19-39.

Godinez, J., & Liu, L. (2018). Corruption and its Effects on FDI: Analysing the Interaction between the Corruption Levels of the Home and Host Countries and its Effects at the Decision-Making Level. Journal of Business Ethics, 147(4), 705-719.

Golder, S. N., & Thomas, J. A. (2014). Portfolio allocation and the vote of no confidence. British Journal of Political Science, 29-39.

Gordon, J. (2012). The US embargo against Cuba and the diplomatic challenges to Extraterritoriality. Fletcher F. World Aff.36, 63.

Gordon, M. W. (1976). The Cuban Nationalizations: The Demise of Foreign Private Property. William S. Hein & Co., Inc.

Gorg, H. (2005). Fancy a Stay at the ‘Hotel California’? The Role of Easy Entry and Exit for FDI. Kyklos, 58 (4), 519–535.

Gould, C. C. (1990). Rethinking democracy: Freedom and social co-operation in politics, economy, and society. Cambridge University Press.

Habib, M. & Zurawicki, L. (2002). Corruption and foreign direct investment. Journal of International Business Studies, 33(2), 291-307.

Hamayotsu, K. (2020). States, Religion, and Democracy in Southeast Asia: Comparative Religious Regime Formation. In Edited by Cammett, M & Jones, P, The Oxford Handbook of Politics in Muslim Societies.

Hardt, M. (2010). The common in communism. Rethinking Marxism22(3), 346-356.

Hatton, B. (2019 October 7). Portugal's Socialists win election, now eye alliances. ABCnews, https://abcnews.go.com/International/wireStory/portugals-socialists-eye-alliances-election-win-66105952

He, Z. (2000). Corruption and anti-corruption in reform China. Communist and Post-Communist Studies, 33(2), 243-270.

Heiman, A., Gordon, B., & Zilberman, D. (2019). Food beliefs and food supply chains: The impact of religion and religiosity in Israel. Food Policy83, 363-369.

Heinzen, J. (2007). The art of the bribe: corruption and everyday practice in the late Stalinist USSR. Slavic Review, 389-412.

Helble, M. 2007. Is god good for trade?, Kyklos, 60(3), 385-413.

Held, D., & McGrew, A. (1993). Globalization and the liberal democratic state. Government and opposition, 28(2), 261-288.

Helfand, M. A. (2019). Jews and the Culture Wars: Consensus and Dissensus in Jewish Religious Liberty Advocacy. San Diego L. Rev., 56, 305.

Heller, J. (2008 September 22). Israel's Peres meets parties after PM Olmert quits. Reuters, https://www.reuters.com/article/us-israel-olmert-resignation-idUSLL27650420080922

Hodge, G. (2018). Privatization: An international review of performance.

Hoffman, R. G. (2015). The age of assassination: monarchy and nation in nineteenth-century Europe. In Rewriting German history. Palgrave Macmillan, London.

Holliday, I. (2005). Doing business with rights violating regimes corporate social responsibility and Myanmar’s military junta. Journal of Business Ethics61(4), 329-342.

Horowitz, I. L. (1995). Cuban communism. Transaction Publishers.

Hovel, R. (2017 November 02). Following the Israeli High Court ruling, the Israeli AG began working to change the guidelines restricting demonstration. Hebrew. Haaretz, https://www.haaretz.co.il/news/law/.premium-1.4565765

Huang, R. L. (2013). Re-thinking Myanmar's political regime: military rule in Myanmar and implications for current reforms. Contemporary Politics19(3), 247-261.

Huber, E., Ragin, C., & Stephens, J. D. (1993). Social democracy, Christian democracy, constitutional structure, and the welfare state. American journal of Sociology99(3), 711-749.

IMF. (2021). World Economic Outlook Database. International Monetary Fund (IMF), https://www.imf.org/en/Countries

Iran Parliament. (2021). Constitution of Iran. Islamic Parliament of Iran, https://en.parliran.ir/eng/en/Constitution

Jalil, A., Qureshi, A., & Feridun, M. (2016). Is corruption good or bad for FDI? Empirical evidence from Asia, Africa and Latin America. Panoeconomicus63(3), 259-271.

Jean-Klein, I. (2001). Nationalism and resistance: The two faces of everyday activism in Palestine during the Intifada. Cultural Anthropology16(1), 83-126.

Jensen, N. (2003). Democratic governance and multinational corporations: Political regimes and inflows of foreign direct investment. International Organization, 57, 587-616.

Jensen, N. (2008). Political risk, democratic institutions, and foreign direct investment. The Journal of Politics70(4), 1040-1052.

Jiang, M., & Esarey, A. (2018). (Un) civil Society in Digital China| Uncivil Society in Digital China: Incivility, Fragmentation, and Political Stability—Introduction. International Journal of Communication12, 17.

Jiang, N., Liping, W., & Sharma, K. (2013). Trends, patters and determinants of foreign direct investment in China. Global Business Review14(2), 201-210.

JTA. (1977 April 8). Rabin Resigns Following Probe into Illegal Bank Accounts Held by Him and His Wife in Washington. https://www.jta.org/1977/04/08/archive/rabin-resigns-following-probe-into-illegal-bank-accounts-held-by-him-and-his-wife-in-washington

Kamenka, E. (2017). Totalitarianism. A Companion to Contemporary Political Philosophy, 821-829.

Keller, J., Mykhyalyshyn, I., & Timur, S. (2016 August 02). The Scale of Turkey's Purge Is Nearly Unprecedented" The New York Times. https://www.nytimes.com/interactive/2016/08/02/world/europe/turkey-purge-erdogan-scale.html

Kendall-Taylor, A., Frantz, E., & Wright, J. (2020). The digital dictators: how technology strengthens autocracy. Foreign Aff.99, 103.

Kenner, D. (2017 March 14). Is Turkey Still a Democracy? Foreign Policy, https://foreignpolicy.com/2017/03/14/is-turkey-still-a-democracy/

Keremoğlu, E., & Weidmann, N. B. (2020). How dictators control the internet: a review essay. Comparative Political Studies53(10-11), 1690-1703.

Keyes, N. (2021 February 1). Developments in Myanmar. World Bank, https://www.worldbank.org/en/news/statement/2021/02/01/developments-in-myanmar

Khan, A., & Estrada, M. A. R. (2016). The effects of terrorism on economic performance: the case of Islamic State in Iraq and Syria (ISIS). Quality & Quantity, 50(4), 1645-1661.

Kim, N. K., & Kroeger, A. M. (2018). Regime and leader instability under two forms of military rule. Comparative Political Studies51(1), 3-37.

Kingsley, P. (2014 August 16). Egypt's Rabaa massacre: one year on. The Guardian, https://www.theguardian.com/world/2014/aug/16/rabaa-massacre-egypt-human-rights-watch

Kirchick, J. (2017). The end of Europe: dictators, demagogues, and the coming dark age. Yale University Press.

Kochan, N. (2013 June 17). The corruption deal of the century: How Guinea lost billions of pounds in Simandou mining licensing. Independent,https://www.independent.co.uk/news/world/africa/corruption-deal-century-how-guinea-lost-billions-pounds-simandou-mining-licensing-8662534.html

Koo, G. Y., & Han, H. E. (2018). To veil or not to veil: Turkish and Iranian hijab policies and the struggle for recognition. Asian Journal of Women's Studies24(1), 47-70.

Korea Assembly. (2012). Constitution of the Republic of Korea. The National Assembly of the Republic of Korea, https://korea.assembly.go.kr:447/res/low_01_read.jsp?boardid=1000000035

Kornai, J. (1992). The socialist system: The political economy of communism. Oxford University Press.

Kornai, J. (1992). The socialist system: The political economy of communism. Oxford University Press.

Kouwenhoven, P. S., Van Thiel, G. J., van der Heide, A., Rietjens, J. A., & van Delden, J. J. (2019). Developments in euthanasia practice in the Netherlands: Balancing professional responsibility and the patient’s autonomy. European Journal of General Practice25(1), 44-48.

Krcmaric, D. (2018). Varieties of civil war and mass killing: Reassessing the relationship between guerrilla warfare and civilian victimization. Journal of Peace Research55(1), 18-31.

Kucera, D. C., & Principi, M. (2014). Democracy and foreign direct investment at the industry level: evidence for US multinationals. Review of World Economics150(3), 595-617.

Kurzman, C. (2009). The unthinkable revolution in Iran. Harvard University Press.

Kynyon, P. (2018 July 26). Turkey's State Of Emergency Ends, While Erdogan's Power Grows And 'Purge' Continues. NPR, https://www.npr.org/2018/07/26/632307755/turkeys-state-of-emergency-ends-while-erdogans-power-grows-and-purge-continues?t=1534676536454&t=1613662842290

Landau, S. (1993). The Guerrilla Wars of Central America: Nicaragua, El Salvador, and Guatemala. Weidenfeld and Nicolson.

Lane, D. (2019). Soviet labour and the ethic of communism: full employment and the labour process in the USSR. Routledge.

Langley, A. (2013 March 09). Prince tells voters to hand over power in Liechtenstein. The Guardian, http://www.theguardian.com/world/2003/mar/09/theobserver1

Lau, C. M., & Bruton, G. D. (2008). FDI in China: What we know and what we need to study next. Academy of Management Perspectives22(4), 30-44.

Levi-Faur, D., & Rozen-Bachar, Z. (2011). Corporate Regulatory Strategies in Context: Telecoms and Electricity Reforms and the New Order of Regulatory Capitalism.  International Journal of Organizational Analysis, 19(3), 235-255.

Li, N. (2008). Religion, opportunism, and international market entry via non-equity alliances or joint ventures. Journal of Business Ethics, 80(4), 771-789.

Li, Q. & Resnick, A. (2003). Reversal of fortunes: Democratic institutions and foreign direct investment inflows to developing countries. International Organization, 57, 1-37.

Li, Q. (2009). Democracy, autocracy, and expropriation of foreign direct investment. Comparative Political Studies42(8), 1098-1127.

Linz, J. J. (2000). Totalitarian and repressive regimes. Lynne Rienner Publishers.

Lis, J. (2018 January 9). Israel Passes Bill That Bans Most Stores From Operating on Shabbat. Haaretz,  https://www.haaretz.com/israel-news/.premium-israel-passes-bill-that-bans-most-stores-from-operating-on-shabbat-1.5729892

Livesey, J. (2001). Making democracy in the French Revolution (Vol. 140). Harvard University Press.

Londregan, J. B., & Poole, K. T. (1990). Poverty, the coup trap, and the seizure of executive power. World Politics: A Quarterly Journal of International Relations, 151-183.

Lord, D. (2019 June 17). What does the Constitution say about third terms for presidents?. Boston 25 News, https://www.boston25news.com/news/trending-now/trump-supporters-may-demand-third-term-what-does-the-constitution-say-about-that/958966348/

Loree, D. & Guisinger, S. (1995). Policy and Non-Policy determinants of US foreign direct investment. Journal of International Business Studies, 26 (2), 281-299.

Luttwak, E. (2016). Coup d'etat: A practical handbook. Harvard University Press.

Machado, M. R. D. A., & Maciel, D. A. (2017). The Battle Over Abortion Rights in Brazil’s State Arenas, 1995-2006. Health and human rights, 19(1), 119.

Mahtani, S., & Lynn, K.Y. (2021 February 1). Myanmar military seizes power in coup after detaining Aung San Suu Kyi. Washington Post, https://www.washingtonpost.com/world/asia_pacific/myanmar-aung-sun-suu-kyi-arrest/2021/01/31/c780ce6a-6419-11eb-886d-5264d4ceb46d_story.html

Malikane, C., & Chitambara, P. (2017). Foreign direct investment, democracy and economic growth in southern Africa. African Development Review, 29(1), 92-102.

MecroPress. (2020 December 26). Trump issues new pardons for crooks and including the father of his son in law Jared Kushner. MercoPress,  https://en.mercopress.com/2020/12/26/trump-issues-new-pardons-for-crooks-and-including-the-father-of-his-son-in-law-jared-kushner

Mill, J. S. (1859). On liberty.

Mooijman, M., Hoover, J., Lin, Y., Ji, H., & Dehghani, M. (2018). Moralization in social networks and the emergence of violence during protests. Nature human behaviour2(6), 389-396.

Moon, C. (2019). Political institutions and FDI inflows in autocratic countries. Democratization, 26(7), 1256-1277.

Mueller, J. W. (2014). Eastern Europe Goes South: Disappearing Democracy in the EU's Newest Members. Foreign Affairs93(2), 14-19.

Mukand, S. W., & Rodrik, D. (2020). The political economy of liberal democracy. The Economic Journal130(627), 765-792.

Napolitano, M. (2018). The Brazilian Military Regime, 1964–1985. In Oxford Research Encyclopedia of Latin American History.

Nasre Esfahani, M., & Rasoulinezhad, E. (2017). Iran’s trade policy of Asianization and de-Europeanization under sanctions. Journal of Economic Studies, 44(4), 552-567.

Nebehay, S. (2021 January 22). Swiss court finds Israeli businessman Beny Steinmetz guilty of corruption. Reuters, https://www.reuters.com/article/us-swiss-steinmetz-idUSKBN29R27Q

Newburn, T. (2020). The 2019 Hong Kong protests: a role for historical sociology. Policing: A Journal of Policy and Practice.

Nigh, D. (1985). The effect of political events on united state direct foreign investment. J. of International Business Studies, 16 (1), 1-17.

Noland, M. (2017). The Risks and Costs of Trade Wars. US-China Cooperation in a Changing Global Economy.

Norris, P., & Inglehart, R. (2019). Cultural backlash: Trump, Brexit, and authoritarian populism. Cambridge University Press.

Nossiter, A. (2019 February 02). Violent ‘Yellow Vest’ Protests in Week 13. New York, https://www.nytimes.com/2019/02/10/world/europe/france-yellow-vest-protests.html?searchResultPosition=6

O'ballance, E. (1998). Civil war in Lebanon, 1975-92. Springer.

O'donell, G. A. (1994). Delegative democracy. Journal of democracy5(1), 55-69.

Oneal, J.R. (1994). The affinity of foreign investors for repressive regimes. Political Research Quarterly, 47, 565-588.

Osborn, A., & Balmforth, T. (2020 March 10). Reuters, Putin approves changes allowing him to stay in power until 2036. https://www.reuters.com/article/us-russia-politics-idUSKBN20X1FD

Pelleg-Sryck, Tamar (2011). "The Mysteries of Administrative Detention". In Baker, Abeer; Matar, Anat (eds.). Threat: Palestinian Political Prisoners in Israel. Pluto Press. pp. 123–135.

Pinkus, L. E., & Meyer, K. (2008). Religious noncoercive and coercive regulations: a new typology for cross-national research. International Journal of Sociology38(3), 82-107.

Porket, J. (1995). Unemployment in capitalist, communist and post-communist economies. Springer.

Przeworski, A. (1986). Capitalism and social democracy. Cambridge University Press.

Psimitis, M. (2011). The protest cycle of spring 2010 in Greece. Social Movement Studies, 10, 191–197.

Rafat, M., & Farahani, M. (2019). The country risks and foreign direct investment (FDI). Iranian Economic Review23(1), 235-260.

Rashid, M., Looi, X. H., & Wong, S. J. (2017). Political stability and FDI in the most competitive Asia Pacific countries. Journal of Financial Economic Policy, 9 (02), 140-155.

Rebelo Morais, J. (2020). Limitation of political rights: the case of the first democratic election in Portugal (1975). Limitation of political rights: the case of the first democratic election in Portugal (1975), 185-194.

Reuters. (2020 May 6). Israel's Supreme Court clears Netanyahu to form government despite corruption charges. Reuters, https://www.reuters.com/article/us-israel-politics-netanyahu-idUSKBN22I35R

Riedel, J., Jin, J., & Gao, J. (2020). How China Grows. Princeton University Press.

Rigby, T. H. (2019). Communist Party membership in the USSR. Princeton University Press.

Roberts, A. (1990). Prolonged Military Occupation: The Israeli-Occupied Territories Since 1967. The American Journal of International Law. 84 (1): 44–103.

Roberts, J. (2019 July 23). 99.86% of us didn’t have a say on Boris Johnson becoming Prime Minister. Metro, https://metro.co.uk/2019/07/23/boris-johnson-become-prime-minister-vote-excluded-99-86-us-10443584/

Robinson, N. (2003). The politics of Russia's partial democracy. Political Studies Review1(2), 149-166.

Rozen-Bakher, Z. (2017). Impact of inward and outward FDI on employment: the role of strategic asset-seeking FDI. Transnational Corporations Review9(1), 16-30.

Rutherford, B. K. (2018). Egypt's New Authoritarianism under Sisi. The Middle East Journal72(2), 185-208.

Samimi, A. J., Moghaddasi, R., & Azizi, K. (2011). Political stability and FDI in OIC countries. Journal of Social and Development Sciences1(1), 18-23.

Sang-Hun, C. (2016 December 09). South Korea Enters Period of Uncertainty With President’s Impeachment. New York Times, https://www.nytimes.com/2016/12/09/world/asia/south-korea-president-park-geun-hye-impeached.html

Saxonberg, S. (2013). Transitions and non-transitions from communism: Regime survival in China, Cuba, North Korea, and Vietnam. Cambridge University Press.

Schmitt, C. (2014). Dictatorship. John Wiley & Sons.

Schmitter, P. C., & Karl, T. L. (1991). What democracy is... and is not. Journal of democracy2(3), 75-88.

Schneider, F. & Frey, B.S. (1985). Economic and political determinants of foreign direct investment. World Development, 13(2), 161-175.

Schneider, N. (2011). Breaking the ‘silence’of the military regime: New politics of memory in Brazil. Bulletin of Latin American Research30(2), 198-212.

Scobell, A. (2005). Making sense of North Korea: Pyongyang and comparative communism. Asian Security1(3), 245-266.

Segers, G. (2021 February 14).  McConnell says Trump was "responsible" for riot after not guilty vote. CBS NEWS, https://www.cbsnews.com/news/mitch-mcconnell-trump-impeachment-vote-senate-speech/

Sethi, D., Guisinger, S.E., Phelan, S.E. & Berg, D.M. (2003). Trends in foreign direct investment flows: a theoretical and empirical analysis. Journal of International Business Studies, 34 (4), 315-326.

Shipley, T. (2018). Ottawa and empire: Canada and the military coup in Honduras. Between the Lines.

Shirbon, E., & Holden, M. (2019 September 24). Supreme Court rules PM Johnson's suspension of parliament was unlawful. Reuters, https://uk.reuters.com/article/uk-britain-eu-court/supreme-court-rules-pm-johnsons-suspension-of-parliament-was-unlawful-idUKKBN1W82RX

Shore, C. (2018). The Crown as proxy for the State? Opening up the black box of constitutional monarchy. The Round Table107(4), 401-416.

Shotar, M. M. (2005). The Attractiveness of Qatar to Foreign Direct Investment, 1980-2002. Applied Econometrics and International Development5(3).

Shyan Fam, K., Waller, D. S., & Zafer Erdogan, B. (2004). The influence of religion on attitudes towards the advertising of controversial products. European Journal of Marketing, 38(5/6), 537-555.

Smith, S. (2014 December 18). Saudi Arabia's New Law Imposes Death Sentence for Bible Smugglers? Christian Post, https://www.christianpost.com/news/saudi-arabias-new-law-imposes-death-sentence-for-bible-smugglers.html

Smooha, S. (2002). The model of ethnic democracy: Israel as a Jewish and democratic state. Nations and nationalism, 8(4), 475-503.

Solender, A. (2020 September 13). Trump Says He Will ‘Negotiate’ Third Term Because He’s ‘Entitled’ To It. Forbes, https://www.forbes.com/sites/andrewsolender/2020/09/13/trump-says-he-will-negotiate-third-term-because-hes-entitled-to-it/?sh=2b71a01c287c

Sombatpoonsiri, J. (2017). The 2014 military coup in Thailand: Implications for political conflicts and resolution. Asian Journal of Peacebuilding5.

Starr, K.J., & Masci, D. (2016 March 8). In Israel, Jews are united by homeland but divided into very different groups. Pew Research Center, https://www.pewresearch.org/fact-tank/2016/03/08/in-israel-jews-are-united-by-homeland-but-divided-into-very-different-groups/

Stewart, H. (2019 May 24). Theresa May announces she will resign on 7 June. Guardian, https://www.theguardian.com/politics/2019/may/24/theresa-may-steps-down-resigns-tory-leader-conservative-brexit

Stoakes, E., & Safi, M. (2021 February 12). Election officials held in Myanmar 'in bid to prove fraud'. The Guardian, https://www.theguardian.com/world/2021/feb/12/election-officials-held-in-myanmar-in-bid-to-prove

Stone, J., & Trew, B. (2019 November 12). Products from illegal Israeli settlements must be labelled, EU’s highest court rules. INDEPENDENT, https://www.independent.co.uk/news/world/europe/israel-illegal-settlement-products-label-eu-high-court-palestine-a9199651.html

Subramaniam, A. (2012). Challenges of protecting India from terrorism. Terrorism and Political Violence24(3), 396-414.

Suh, J. J. (Ed.). (2012). Origins of North Korea's Juche: Colonialism, war, and development. Lexington books.

Sullivan, M. P. (2007, October). Cuba's Political Succession: From Fidel to Raul Castro. Congressional Research Service, the Library of Congress.

Sutton, K. (2017 March 29). Warren, Carper petition Ethics Office for information on Ivanka Trump’s White House role. Politico, https://www.politico.com/story/2017/03/elizabeth-warren-tom-carper-ethics-letter-ivanka-trump-236636

Svolik, M. (2012) The politics of authoritarian rule. Cambridge University Press.

Swann, J., & Félix, J. (2013). The crisis of the absolute monarchy: from the old regime to the French Revolution (No. 184). Oxford University Press.

Sznajder, M., & Roniger, L. (2003). Trends and constraints of partial democracy in Latin America. Cambridge Review of International Affairs16(2), 323-341.

Tabash, M. I., & Dhankar, R. S. (2014). Islamic banking and economic growth: An empirical evidence from Qatar. Journal of Applied Economics and Business2(1), 51-67.

Takeyh, R. (2021). The Last Shah: America, Iran, and the Fall of the Pahlavi Dynasty. Council on Foreign Relations B.

Teixeira, A. A., & Guimarães, L. (2015). Corruption and FDI: Does the Use of Distinct Proxies for Corruption Matter?. Journal of African Business16(1-2), 159-179.

Tendi, B. M. (2020). The motivations and dynamics of Zimbabwe’s 2017 military coup. African Affairs119(474), 39-67.

The Hindu. (2019 June 16). Israel PM’s wife convicted of misusing public funds. The Hindu, https://www.thehindu.com/news/international/israel-pm-netanyahus-wife-admits-criminal-wrongdoing-in-meals-catering-case/article27955841.ece

The Knesset. (2019). Knesset passes Jewish nation-state bill into law". The Knesset, https://main.knesset.gov.il/EN/Pages/default.aspx

The Knesset. (2021). All Governments of Israel. The Knesset, https://main.knesset.gov.il/EN/mk/government/Pages/governments.aspx?govId=35

The Knesset. (2021). Israeli Declaration of Independence. The Knesset, https://main.knesset.gov.il/About/Occasion/Pages/IndDeclaration.aspx

Thiyagarajan, A., Bhattacharya, S., & Kaushal, K. (2018). Homelessness: An Emerging Threat. Inform5(2), 18-20.

Thyne, C. L., & Powell, J. M. (2016). Coup d’état or coup d'Autocracy? How coups impact democratization, 1950–2008. Foreign policy analysis12(2), 192-213.

Times of Israel. (2018 January 20). Thousands protest in Ashdod against Shabbat store closures. Times of Israel, Thousands protest in Ashdod against Shabbat store closures | The Times of Israel

Tomashevskiy, A. (2017). Investing in violence: Foreign direct investment and coups in repressive regimes. The Journal of Politics, 79(2), 409-423.

Treisman, D. (Ed.). (2018). The New Autocracy: Information, Politics, and Policy in Putin's Russia. Brookings Institution Press.

Trevino, L.J. & Mixon, F.G. (2004). Strategic factors affecting foreign direct investment decisions by multi-national enterprises in Latin America. Journal of World Business, 39 (3), 233-243.

Tullock, G. (2012). Autocracy. Springer Science & Business Media.

Tuman, J.P. & Emmert, C.F. (2004). The political economy of U.S. foreign direct investment in Latin America: A reappraisal. Latin American Research Review, 39, 9-28.

University of Bern (UNIBE). (2020). Constitution of Iran. Switzerland: University of Bern, https://www.servat.unibe.ch/icl/ir00000_.html

USCIRF. (2017). International Religious Freedom Report, 2017. U.S. Department of State, https://www.uscirf.gov/sites/default/files/2017.USCIRFAnnualReport.pdf

Von Soest, C., & Grauvogel, J. (2017). Identity, procedures and performance: how repressive regimes legitimize their rule. Contemporary Politics23(3), 287-305.

Wach, J. (2016). The comparative study of religions. Columbia University Press (1958).

Wagner, S. (2008). British intelligence and the Jewish resistance movement in the Palestine mandate, 1945–46. Intelligence and National Security23(5), 629-657.

Walsh, J. L. (2017). Success Characteristics Of Foreign Direct Investment In Cuba. Global Journal of Business Research11(2), 43-53.

Wedeman, B., Reza Sayah, R., & Smith, M. (2013 July 4). Coup topples Egypt's Morsy; deposed president under 'house arrest'. CNN, https://edition.cnn.com/2013/07/03/world/meast/egypt-protests

Weiss, D. C. (2008). The Foreign Corrupt Practices Act, SEC disgorgement of profits, and the evolving international bribery regime: Weighing proportionality, retribution, and deterrence. Mich. J. Int'l L.30, 471.

Weiss, M. A. (2007, April). Arab League Boycott of Israel. LIBRARY OF CONGRESS WASHINGTON DC CONGRESSIONAL RESEARCH SERVICE.

White, N. D. (2019). Ending the US embargo of Cuba: international law in dispute. Journal of Latin American Studies, 51(1), 163-186.

Wijsen, F. J. S. (2004). Seeds of conflict: Religious tensions in Tanzania. Paulines Publications Africa.

Wilkinson, S. I. (2009). Riots. Annual Review of Political Science12, 329-343.

Wills, E. (2019 March 25). MPs seize control of process as they back plan to hold 'indicative votes' on leaving EU. Evening Standard, https://commonslibrary.parliament.uk/parliament-and-elections/parliament/taking-control-of-the-order-paper/

Wintrobe, R. (2000). The political economy of dictatorship. Cambridge University Press.

Wise, P. (2019 January 17). Portugal hit by nurses’ ‘surgical strike’ movement. Financial Times, https://www.ft.com/content/26b8649e-1983-11e9-b93e-f4351a53f1c3

Wong, L., & Kinglun, N. (1997). Unemployment and policy responses in Mainland China. Issues & Studies33(1), 43-63.

Woodhead, L., Partridge, C., & Kawanami, H. (Eds.). (2016). Religions in the modern world: Traditions and transformations. Routledge.

WPR. (2021). Former USSR. World Population Review (WPR),https://worldpopulationreview.com/country-rankings/former-ussr-countries

Wright, J., & Bak, D. (2016). Measuring autocratic regime stability. Research & Politics, 3(1), 1-7.

Wynbrandt, J. (2010). A brief history of Saudi Arabia. Infobase Publishing.

Xuan, N. T., & Xing, Y. (2008). Foreign direct investment and exports The experiences of Vietnam 1. Economics of transition16(2), 183-197.

Yang, B. (2007). Autocracy, democracy, and FDI inflows to the developing countries. International Economic Journal, 21(3), 419-439.

Younis, A. (2016 April 28). Jordan changes constitution to give King more power. Al Jazeera, https://www.aljazeera.com/news/2016/4/28/jordan-changes-constitution-to-give-king-more-power

Yue, X., & Yang, G. (2017). Urbanization, the State's Infrastructural Power, and Political Stability in China. CASS Journal of Political Science, 03.

Zheng, S. (2017). China’s Political Stability: Comparisons and Reflections. In Governance, Domestic Change, and Social Policy in China (pp. 149-169). Palgrave Macmillan, New York.

Dr. Ziva Rozen-Bakher

Dr. Ziva Rozen-Bakher

Researcher in Risks for Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) and International Trade

Political Risks, Economic Risks, Strategic Risks

https://www.rozen-bakher.com/
Previous
Previous

PD2 - Research Paper. Rozen-Bakher, Z. Are Multinational Enterprises’ (MNEs) Theories explained the reality of Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) and International Trade in the 21st Century?

Next
Next

PD6 - Research Paper. Rozen-Bakher, Z. Technological Location Factors of Foreign Direct Investment (FDI): R&D Expenditure, Technological Strategic Assets, Technical Labour, and ICT Infrastructure